1. Introduction
Recent studies suggest that a high degree of income inequality strengthens the role of family background in determining children’s life outcomes (Corak, 2013; Krueger, 2012; Solon, 1992). The present work seeks to provide a descriptive yet structured discussion of intergenerational economic mobility in the highly unequal context of Mexico: its trends, its regional variability, and its plausible relationship with income inequality.
Our research question is based on the economic literature that focuses on income persistence across generations, particularly in studies of the United States (U.S.) (Solon 1992, 1999, 2002; Mazumder, 2005).1 The U.S. has relatively low mobility in comparison to other advanced economies, but greater mobility than developing countries (Mazumder, 2018; Corak, 2013; Delajara et al., 2020).
Notwithstanding extensive interest in the topic, the literature examining income mobility in developing countries remains limited because of the lack of high-quality datasets linking adult children’s income with that of their parents (Rojas-Valdés, 2012).2 To overcome this challenge, recent work relies on analyzing the broader concept of social intergenerational mobility through socioeconomic or wealth indexes (e.g., Torche and Spilerman, 2010; Torche, 2010, 2014).3 Although we do not deny that such an approach allows the inclusion of aspects of intergenerational mobility other than the economic one, a significant limitation of this approach is the underlying assumption of homogenous individual preferences across time and place toward certain assets.4
In the present study, the key issue is to compute family earnings while children are growing up. In the Mexican census, parents’ and children’s earnings are not linked. We, therefore, follow previous literature to define synthetic families (Aronson and Mazumder, 2008). First, we compute parents’ earnings for children in earlier censuses by relevant birth cohort, the state in which they were born, and census year. In later censuses, the adult children report their earnings. Second, we obtain the average of parents’ earnings by birth cohort, the state where they were born, and census year. Third, when parents’ earnings are available for a particular birth cohort and state of birth for more than one census year, we calculate a multi-year average as a way to address short-term shocks in family earnings (Mazumder, 2005). In this way, we are able to match grown children with synthetic families, and their synthetic earnings by cohort and the state where they were born. For example, individuals reporting earnings in 2015 who were born in Mexico City between 1986 and 1990 are matched with the average earnings of families whose children were born in the same years in Mexico City. Our measures of intergenerational economic mobility thus account for the extent to which the earnings of adult children differ from synthetic family earnings.
As a first step, this work presents aggregate estimates of intergenerational economic mobility at the national level. The empirical strategy follows previous literature (e.g., Aaronson and Mazumder, 2008; and Lee and Solon, 2009), regressing the log of adult children’s earnings on the log of synthetic family earnings, with different sets of controls. The regression coefficient is the intergenerational elasticity (IGE), and it describes the extent to which family economic background persists over generations. A previously reported IGE for Mexico is 36 percent lower than ours (Rojas-Valdés, 2012).
The empirical strategy allows for both time-invariant and timevariant estimates. An initial result without controls shows that a 1 percent increase in synthetic family earnings yields a 0.45 percent increase in adult children’s earnings. Controlling for cohort fixed effects, year fixed effects, region of birth fixed effects, age, and earnings profile, the same increase yields a 0.47 percent increase in adult children’s earnings. Our estimate that is most comparable to the U.S. estimate reported in Aaronson and Mazumder (2008) shows an IGE coefficient for Mexico that is 16 percent greater than the American one.
We conducted several robustness checks to test the stability of our estimates, and analysis of different sample characteristics considered in previous studies showed no major changes. The estimates are robust with restrictions on the age of adult children (25 or older and 30 or older) and parents (between 40 and 50 years). We also examine synthetic fathers’ earnings as an alternative independent variable, which yields a similar IGE estimate. Furthermore, the stability of our baseline estimate provides a certain degree of confidence in our empirical strategy.
The time-variant estimates, which included interaction terms of synthetic family earnings with birth cohorts and census years, depict the intergenerational economic mobility trend between 1995 and 2015 (Almond and Mazumder, 2005; Aaronson and Mazumder, 2008). If we restrict the specification to account only for the interaction between family earnings and year, there is a decrease in IGE that is significant only over a long period. If we restrict it to account only for the interaction between birth cohort and family earnings, the IGE also decreases across birth cohorts. The less restrictive specification, which includes both year and birth cohort estimates, confirms an increase in mobility from 1995 to 2010 and from 1995 to 2015, and the increase is driven by the census year interaction terms rather than birth cohort interactions. These patterns are robust to changes in sample features and alternative dependent and independent variables, and are consistent with the decline that has been found in returns to schooling and in inequality in Mexico (Campos-Vázquez et al., 2012). However, future research also needs to address whether measurement error is affecting the estimates’ magnitude.
We also compute the IGE estimates by region. These suggest the presence of an important geographical variation in intergenerational mobility across regions of birth. People born in the south face the lowest degree of relative intergenerational mobility and those in the north face the highest. These results are consistent with recent efforts to estimate social mobility across Mexican states (Delajara et al., 2020).
Finally, we compute a comparison of the Mexican IGE with other countries, which provides a broad portrait of the underlying factors determining children’s outcomes as adults (Solon, 2004; Corak, 2016). The heterogeneity found confirms that Mexico has a lower degree of intergenerational mobility than more advanced economies.
The rest of this paper is structured as follows. The next section describes the data and our synthetic approach, and it presents our empirical strategy. The third section presents the main results and robustness checks, and the fourth section offers some conclusions.
2. Methods
2.1. Data
This study employs micro-level data from Mexican censuses conducted by the National Institute of Statistics and Geography (Instituto Nacional de Estadística y Geografía, INEGI) in 1990, 1995, 2000, 2010, and 2015; these data are available on the IPUMS International web site (https://international.ipums.org/inter-national). The sample fraction available is 10 percent for 1990, 0.4 percent for 1995, 10.6 percent for 2010, and 9.5 percent for 2015. The universe for all samples is individuals aged 12 and above. Data on earnings from the 1970 census are not comparable to earnings reported in the selected censuses, and the 1980 census microdata is no longer available since it was lost in the 1985 Mexico City earthquake.5
The censuses collect data on labor income and earnings for the previous month. These earnings include wage income from businesses, farms, and other sources. One of the main advantages of focusing on earnings is that earnings capacity, such as that represented by skills and effort, is transferred from parents to children differently than other assets. Earnings capacity can be transferred through investment in human capital (Becker et al., 2018), while other assets are transferred directly from parents to children (Becker and Tomes, 1986). In this sense, earnings provide the best proxy for opportunities related to individual merit (Mazumder, 2005).
Mexican censuses do not link individuals across years. We thus follow the synthetic approach of Aaronson and Mazumder (2008), which requires a core sample that clearly distinguishes between adult children and synthetic families, allowing us to compare how much adult children’s earnings differ from their synthetic family earnings. We define adult children as men who are 20 years old in the 1995-2015 censuses; these individuals are old enough to report earnings.6 Synthetic families are defined as representative family units where adult children are likely to be members, as determined by two variables: the state in which they were born and their birth cohort. The earnings of such representative families are the synthetic family earnings. With these definitions, synthetic families are observed in the 1990, 1995, and 2000 censuses, and adult children are observed in those of 1995, 2000, 2010, and 2015. For example, a 30-year-old man born in Mexico City who reports earnings in the 2010 census is virtually matched with a Mexico City family reporting earnings in the 1990 census, whose children were approximately 10 years old at that time. For the purposes of this study, we consider four birth cohorts: 1971-75, 1976-80, 1981-85, and 1986-90. We take the state where they were born, as reported in the censuses; since there are 32 states, the number of representative families is 128.
Once we have defined the core sample and the linkage between individuals and families across censuses, we compute synthetic family earnings. First, for the 1990-2000 censuses, we assign cohorts to children born in Mexico. During this time, children live with their parents; hence, by assigning a birth-cohort we are identifying potential families of future generations. This task is conditional on the available information. For instance, in the 1990 census, we can identify individuals from all birth cohorts, as shown in table 1, column (1); in other words, all men born between 1971 and 1990 are children in the 1990 census. Column (2) shows their age. However, for the 1995 and 2000 censuses we can only assign the 1981-85 and 1986-90 birth cohorts, since individuals born in prior cohorts have become adult children by the time of those censuses, as shown in column (4). By the time of the 2010 and 2015 censuses, all of the children have become adults and no families are observed.
Family |
Adult Children |
|||||||
Cohort |
Census Year |
Age |
Mean earnings |
Census Year |
Age |
Mean earnings |
Obs. |
|
(1) |
(2) |
(3) |
(4) |
(5) |
(6) |
(7) |
||
1995 |
20-24 |
2,795 |
14,261 |
|||||
1971-75 |
1990 |
15-19 |
5,653 |
2000 |
25-29 |
4,714 |
365,869 |
|
2010 |
35-40 |
6,429 |
352,873 |
|||||
2015 |
41-45 |
6,381 |
258,422 |
|||||
1990 |
10-14 |
2000 |
20-24 |
2,852 |
403,698 |
|||
1976-80 |
5,620 |
2010 |
30-34 |
5,760 |
365,882 |
|||
1995 |
15-19 |
2015 |
35-40 |
5,997 |
277,253 |
|||
1990 |
5-9 |
2010 |
25-29 |
4,798 |
381,373 |
|||
1981-85 |
1995 |
10-14 |
5,677 |
|||||
2000 |
15-19 |
2015 |
30-34 |
5,845 |
286,604 |
|||
1990 |
0-4 |
2010 |
20-24 |
2,865 |
458,567 |
|||
1986-90 |
1995 |
5-9 |
5,804 |
|||||
2000 |
10-14 |
2015 |
25-29 |
5,251 |
289,102 |
Notes: Column (1) shows the correspondence between birth cohorts and the census year in which families are virtually observed, column (2) the age of individuals when they lived with their families, column (3) synthetic family earnings (monthly labor income in 2010 MXN), column (4) the years when adult children (men) are observed, column (5) their ages, column (6) their average earnings (monthly labor income in 2010 MXN), and column (7) the number of observations in each census. Synthetic family earnings consider parents with zero earnings. Average earnings of adult children include those with zero earnings.
Once children are assigned to a birth cohort, we add the earnings of household heads and spouses to compute parental earnings in each census year. We also assign these earnings to children. In the case of families with children belonging to different cohorts or who were born in different states, the same parental earnings are assigned to each one. We assign family earnings regardless of other family characteristics (such as family size, children’s gender, or parents’ marital status). As a final step, we compute synthetic family earnings (SFE). These are the average parental earnings assigned to children i that were born in state s, where c = {1, ..., 32}; in birth cohort c, where c = {1971 − 75, 1976 − 80, 1981 − 85, 1986 − 90}; observed in census year t, where t = {1990, 1995, 2000, 2010}. This can be written as follows:
This definition allows us to compute family earnings for the same cohort at different points in time. For example, in table 1, column (1), we can observe that for the birth cohort 1981-85 it is possible to estimate the SFE in 1990, 1995, and 2000. In such cases, we calculate the period average to smooth cyclical variation in the family’s earnings (Mazumder, 2005). This results in an SFE for each birth cohort and state of birth. Table 1, column (3) shows the SFE for each cohort. These earnings turn out to be very similar for the 1971-75, 1976-80 and 1981-85 birth cohorts, just above MXN 5,600 per month, while for the 1986-90 birth cohort the SFE is around MXN 5,800 per month. Column (6) shows the mean of adult children’s monthly earnings, including those individuals reporting zero earnings. This amount ranges from MXN 2,795 to MXN 6,381. Column (7) reports the number of observations per cohort in every census. The total sample has approximately 2.6 million observations.
2.1. Empirical strategy
The empirical strategy follows the existing literature for estimating intergenerational economic persistence by allowing for time-varying estimates (e.g., Aaronson and Mazumder, 2008; Lee and Solon, 2009). The basic specification can be written as follows:
where
The coefficients of interest are
Specification (2) also accounts for additional factors that, according to the literature, could bias the results. The vector
Specification (2) is similar to one employing state of birth and birth cohorts as instrumental variables (Aaronson and Mazumder, 2008). If these variables exogenously determine family earnings from previous generations, it is possible for the OLS estimate for
One concern is that specification (2) does not allow us to analyze the importance of birthplace in determining adult children’s outcomes. Since part of the exogenous source of variation in synthetic family earnings is the state of birth, that variation is lost in the analysis of intergenerational mobility across states of birth. However, we overcome this problem by allowing synthetic family earnings to vary across regions of birth. We consider the four regions defined by the Mexican central bank (Banco de México, 2016): north (Baja California, Sonora, Chihuahua, Coahuila, Nuevo León, and Tamaulipas), north-center (Sinaloa, Durango, Zacatecas, San Luis Potosí, Nayarit, Tlaxcala, Aguascalientes, Jalisco, Colima, and Michoacán), center (Mexico City, Estado de México, Morelos, Puebla, Tlaxcala, Hidalgo, Querétaro, and Guanajuato), and south (Guerrero, Oaxaca, Chiapas, Veracruz, Tabasco, Campeche, Yucatán, and Quintana Roo). Since each of these regions contains several states, it is possible to rely on some variation to compute IGE estimates by region of birth. For this task, we use the following specification:
Specification (3) estimates the time-invariant IGE for each birth region, and
A second concern is the cross-country comparability of our timeinvariant IGE estimate, which is crucial to understanding the underlying factors driving intergenerational economic mobility (Corak, 2016; Solon, 2004). To address this problem, we follow the framework proposed by Corak (2006) for cross-country comparison. Employing this framework, the author uses metadata from the literature to select representative estimates for several countries and scale them by a factor that considers the U.S. as a reference and a U.S. estimate that would adjust for the difference in sample characteristics and methodologies across countries.15 The scaling factor is defined as follows:
where
3. Results
3.1 Time-invariant and time-variant IGE estimates
Table 2 presents time-invariant IGE estimates at the national level, in which
A first benchmark for comparison is the baseline IGE estimate for the U.S. reported in Aaronson and Mazumder (2008), which is 0.43. If we consider the main estimate in column (5) to have the most similar specification and sample characteristics, persistence is greater in Mexico. A second benchmark uses the intergenerational income elasticities reported by Rojas-Valdés (2012), and it varies significantly, depending on the type of estimate and sample characteristics. For his two-sample instrumental variable estimate, the IGE is about 0.31, which is 36 percent lower than the estimate in column (5), while his estimate for a pseudo-panel sample yields a value of 0.6, which is 20 percent higher than our estimate.
Dependent variable: log of adult children’s earnings |
||||||
(1) |
(2) |
(3) |
(4) |
(5) |
(6) |
|
log(SFE) |
0.451*** (0.036) |
0.500*** (0.038) |
0.459*** (0.038) |
0.479*** (0.037) |
0.500*** (0.038) |
0.468*** (0.033) |
Cohort F.E. |
No |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Year F.E. |
No |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Region of birth F.E. |
No |
No |
No |
No |
No |
Yes |
Age |
No |
No |
Yes |
No |
Yes |
Yes |
Earnings profile |
No |
No |
No |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Observations |
2,641,109 |
2,641,109 |
2,641,109 |
2,641,109 |
2,641,109 |
2,641,109 |
R2 |
0.05 |
0.11 |
0.11 |
0.11 |
0.11 |
0.11 |
Notes: OLS estimates for the time-invariant intergenerational elasticity. The dependent variable is the log of adult children’s monthly earnings. The independent variable is the log of average monthly synthetic family earnings by state of birth and birth cohort of previous generations. Standard error adjusting for clustering within state of birth in parentheses. Columns report results for different sets of controls. These controls are cohort fixed effects, census year fixed effects, region of birth fixed effects, a quadratic polynomial for age, and a quadratic polynomial for age where each term interacts with synthetic family earnings. Coefficients statistically different from zero at the following significance levels: * 10 percent, ** 5 percent, and *** 1 percent.
One concern here is the extent to which our IGE time-invariant estimates are robust to sampling changes. There are four alternative samples of interest: 1) families whose children belong to the same birth cohort (Aaronson and Mazumder, 2008), 2) adult children aged 25 or older (e.g., Solon, 1992), 3) adult children aged 30 or older (e.g., Mazumder, 2001), and 4) synthetic families with parents aged 40-50 and children 30 or older (e.g., Zimmerman, 1992). Following specification (2) and the appropriate restriction to estimate the IGE, figure 1, panel A shows the resulting OLS estimates for this robustness check, with the estimates indicated by blue squares with 95 percent confidence intervals. The estimates are similar for most of the sample.
Notes: The figure shows IGE estimates for different samples along with their clustered (within state of birth) confidence intervals at the 95 percent level. The first sample is the baseline, the second focuses on families whose children belong to the same birth cohort to compute family earnings, the third and fourth restrict the age of adult children, while the fifth also restricts the sample to fathers within a specific age range. Panel A employs adult children’s earnings as the outcome variable, while Panel B employs family earnings of adult children as the outcome variable. There are two independent variables: family earnings (squares) and father’s earnings (triangles).
Restricting the sample to families whose children are in the same birth cohort yields an estimate of 0.26, 44 percent lower than the baseline estimate. If the age of adult children is restricted to 25 years or older, the estimate increases to 0.486, and if it is restricted to 29 years or older, it increases to 0.499. Restricting both children’s and fathers’ age leads to an estimate of 0.479, suggesting that considering children between 20 and 24 years old does not substantially decrease the baseline estimate (as suggested by Haider and Solon, 2006).
A substantial part of the literature has focused on studying fathers’ rather than family earnings (Solon, 1999). We thus test the robustness of our estimates by using synthetic fathers’ instead of family earnings, while also considering different sample characteristics. Figure 1, panel A indicates the corresponding IGE estimates with triangles, along with their 95 percent confidence intervals: considering fathers’ earnings slightly increases the estimates. The IGE estimate with the baseline sample shows that a 1 percent increase in fathers’ earnings is associated with a 0.47 percent increase in adult children’s income. The estimate across samples also remains similar, reaching a maximum value of 0.50 if the sample is restricted to children aged 30 years or older, with a value of 0.49 if fathers’ age is restricted.
A second concern about our IGE estimates is the extent to which economic persistence takes place in family earnings rather than in adult children’s earnings. For this robustness check, we use specification (2), changing the dependent variable to the log of family earnings, that is, adding the earnings of adult children and their spouses. Figure 1, panel B plots these IGE estimates along with their 95 percent confidence intervals across different samples and independent variables. In the baseline sample, the estimates increase substantially, by 22.8 percent with respect to the baseline estimate. The increase is consistent across different samples, with slight differences due to adult children’s age or the use of father’s instead of family earnings as the key independent variable. Although we are not able to formally test the factors driving the IGE upwards, it may be that marital sorting factors lead to a higher level of economic persistence across generations (Chadwick and Solon, 2002; Ermisch et al., 2006). In this sense, intergenerational mobility in Mexico has an important component derived from marriage decisions.
3.2 Time-variant and cohort-variant IGE estimates
Table 3 reports time-variant (census year) and cohort-variant (birth cohort) IGE trends for the period 1995-2015. As mentioned above, we obtain a census-year trend after setting
Dependent variable: log of adult children’s earnings |
|||||
(1) |
(2) |
(3) |
(4) |
(5) |
|
log(SFE) |
- - |
- - |
- - |
- - |
0.468*** (0.033) |
x census year |
|||||
1995 |
0.551*** (0.048) |
0.770*** (0.058) |
- - |
- - |
- - |
2000 |
0.514*** (0.061) |
0.673*** (0.053) |
- - |
- - |
-0.095 (0.080) |
2010 |
0.322*** (0.037) |
0.470*** (0.040) |
- |
- |
-0.333*** (0.073) |
2015 |
0.417*** (0.029) |
0.474*** (0.033) |
- - |
- - |
-0.345*** (0.085) |
x birth cohort |
|||||
1971-75 |
- - |
- - |
0.525*** (0.034) |
0.504*** (0.037) |
- - |
1976-80 |
- - |
- - |
0.424*** (0.031) |
0.390*** (0.031) |
-0.024 (0.023) |
1981-85 |
- - |
- - |
0.379*** (0.034) |
0.326*** (0.051) |
0.003 (0.035) |
1986-90 |
- - |
- - |
0.324*** (0.031) |
0.290*** (0.053) |
0.048 (0.041) |
Cohort F.E. |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Year F.E. |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Region of birth F.E. |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Age |
No |
Yes |
No |
Yes |
Yes |
Earnings profile |
No |
Yes |
No |
Yes |
Yes |
Observations |
2,641,109 |
2,641,109 |
2,641,109 |
2,641,109 |
2,641,109 |
R2 |
0.10 |
0.11 |
0.11 |
0.11 |
0.11 |
Notes: OLS estimates for time-variant and cohort-variant intergenerational elasticities. The dependent variable is the log of adult children’s monthly earnings. In columns (1)-(2), the independent variables are the log of average monthly synthetic family earnings interacting with dummy variables indicating the year adult children’s earnings are observed. In columns (3)-(4), the independent variables are the log of average monthly synthetic family earnings interacting with dummy variables indicating the relevant birth cohort. In column (5), all interactions are included. Standard errors adjusting for clustering within state of birth in parentheses. Columns report results for different sets of controls. Columns (1) and (3) include census-year fixed effects, cohort fixed effects, and region of birth fixed effects. Columns (2) and (4) include a quadratic polynomial for age and a quadratic polynomial for age where each term interacts with the log of synthetic family earnings. Coefficients statistically different from zero at the following significance levels: * 10 percent, ** 5 percent, and *** 1 percent.
In general, table 3 shows a decreasing pattern in the intergenerational elasticity across census years and cohorts. This would suggest that relative intergenerational mobility increased between 1995 and 2015. Most coefficients are positive and statistically significant at the 1 percent level, allowing us to compute IGE estimates for different points in time and specific birth cohorts. With respect to the censusyear trend, column (1) and column (2) show a similar decreasing pattern in the time-variant IGE estimate, where the main difference is that the absence of life-cycle controls yields estimates that are likely to be biased downward. The preferred census-year estimate, shown in column (2), suggests that the IGE decreases from 0.77 in 1995 to 0.67 in 2000, and decreases more in 2010, to 0.47. After that it remains at a similar value for 2015. In fact, by computing confidence intervals at the 95 percent level, it turns out that the decrease in the IGE estimates is particularly significant when comparing estimates for 1995 or 2000 with those for 2010.
For the birth cohort estimates, columns (3) and (4) also show a decreasing pattern, and life-cycle controls play a less important role in their magnitude. The preferred birth cohort estimate, reported in column (4), suggests that the IGE for individuals in the 1971-75 birth cohort is 0.5. The estimate decreases to 0.4 for those in the 1976-80 cohort, and to approximately 0.3 for those in the 1981-85 and 1986-90 birth cohorts. It should be noted that with confidence intervals at the 95 percent level for the point estimates, the IGE differences are statistically significant only when comparing the oldest and youngest cohorts. These results are in line with the census-year trend result, where younger generations have a higher degree of intergenerational mobility.
The last column, which considers our most flexible specification, also supports the argument that intergenerational mobility has increased in recent times, and enables us to determine whether the increase is driven by census-year or birth-cohort effects: the prevailing effect is the one observed across census years. Interpretation of these estimates suggests that people in the 1971-75 birth cohort have an estimated IGE of 0.8 in 1995. This estimate decreases to approximately 0.5 in 2010 and 2015; the estimate for 2000 is not statistically significant. The fact that interactions between cohort and family earnings are not statistically significant indicates that all cohorts follow the same trend.
These results appear to be similar to those from a recent estimate by Torche (2020), who builds a socioeconomic index accounting for a family’s durable goods, assets, and services as a proxy for economic persistence across birth cohorts, and finds that intergenerational economic association increases for individuals born between 1950 and 1970, but decreases for younger cohorts.
We also perform robustness checks to test the sensitivity of our preferred IGE estimate, reported in column (2) of table 3. First, we randomly assign a birth state to individuals before computing the IGE estimates; as expected the coefficients are very close to zero. Second, we use the log of fathers’ earnings as the key independent variable, and find similar estimates, with the same pattern in the IGE estimates. Third, we regress the log of family earnings of adult children on the log of synthetic family earnings. These estimates substantially increase with respect to baseline estimates, but the pattern remains similar. Although further research is needed to account for alternative sources of variation, the evidence points to a slight improvement in relative intergenerational economic mobility (that is, lower persistence) in Mexico from 1995 to 2010-2015.
3.3 Regional-variation of the IGE estimate
Table 4 shows the results for IGE by region of birth. As previously explained, we consider four regions: north, center, north-center, and south. Column (1) reports the IGE estimates for the north, column (2) for the center, column (3) for the north-center, and column (4) for the south. All estimates account for census-year fixed effects, birth-cohort fixed effects, and lifecycle factors. In general, the estimates suggest that region of birth plays an important role in intergenerational mobility, and that there is heterogeneous mobility across regions. The highest level of intergenerational mobility is in the north, followed by the center, then the north-center, and finally the south. A 1 percent increase in synthetic family earnings is associated with a 0.43 percent increase in adult children’s earnings in the north, 0.49 percent in the center, 0.52 percent in the north-center, and 0.53 percent in the south. Unfortunately, there is not enough data to identify statistical differences between regions.
Dependent variable: log of adult children’s earnings | ||||
North (1) |
Center (2) |
North-center (3) |
South (4) |
|
log(SFE) |
0.434*** (0.025) |
0.496*** (0.008) |
0.515*** (0.14) |
0.534*** (0.025) |
Cohort F.E. |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Year F.E. |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Region of birth F.E. |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Age |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Earnings profile |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Yes |
Observations |
326,641 |
909,552 |
560,137 |
844,779 |
R2 |
0.07 |
0.10 |
0.08 |
0.06 |
Notes: The table reports OLS estimates for the time-invariant intergenerational elasticity. The dependent variable is the log of adult children’s monthly earnings. The independent variable is the log of average monthly synthetic family earnings by state of birth and birth cohort of previous generations. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Columns report results for different sets of controls. These controls are cohort fixed effects, census year fixed effects, region of birth fixed effect, a quadratic polynomial for age, and a quadratic polynomial for age where each term interacts with synthetic family earnings. Coefficients statistically significant different from zero at the following significance levels: * 10 percent, ** 5 percent, and *** 1 percent. Supplementary materials document these results with a map of Mexico and its regions.
These results are in line with recent evidence, coinciding mainly in the fact that the southern region has the lowest level of intergenerational mobility in the country. Delajara and Gran˜a (2018) and Vélez-Grajales et al. (2018) used the 2011 ESRU Social Mobility Survey in Mexico to compute relative intergenerational social mobility with a wealth index for the same regions. They find the lowest relative mobility in the south and the highest in the north-central region. More recently, Delajara et al. (2020) employed the 2017 edition of the same survey to estimate social mobility across the states of Mexico and across wealth ranks. These authors find that southern states have the lowest degree of social mobility (absolute upward mobility), while northern states have the highest (relative and absolute upward mobility).
The robustness checks for these estimates were limited. The first was to consider specification (2). In this case, we examine the interaction between synthetic family earnings and region of birth, with the restrictions
3.4. Cross-country differences, Mexico, and the Great Gatsby curve
Cross-country differences can shed light on the role of three fundamental factors in determining children’s economic outcomes: family background, labor markets, and the role of the state (Solon, 2004). Corak (2016) argues that cross-country differences are related to differences in the transmission of inequality due to differences in the investments in children made by different societies, and the return on those investments. These processes include family background (i.e., investment in human capital), labor markets (i.e., returns to education), public policy (i.e., progressive reforms like increasing education and health care for the poor) and their interactions. By understanding how these factors influence intergenerational earnings mobility in Mexico and its differences with other countries, we can understand better what is needed to change the ways in which inequality is transmitted from one generation to the next.17
To examine the case of Mexico in a cross-country framework, we follow the methodology proposed by Corak (2006), which scales the most reasonable IGE estimates for different countries to a representative (anchor) estimate for the U.S., adjusting also for differences in sample characteristics and methods. The anchor is 0.462 for countries other than the U.S., Canada, and the U.K. (Corak, 2006). For Mexico, we consider the IGE estimate based on regressing the log of adult children’s earnings on the log of synthetic fathers’ earnings, controlling for all the factors specified in equation (2) except birth region. This estimate is 0.52. Then, by following a similar specification with PSID data, we estimate an IGE of 0.479, which is similar to the estimate obtained by Grawe (2004) for the U.S. Finally, by using equation (4) we obtain an IGE of 0.5 for Mexico.
Figure 2 is the Great Gatsby curve that shows how Mexico compares with other countries in terms of intergenerational economic mobility (x-axis) and inequality (y-axis), (Corak, 2016; Krueger, 2012). In general, the graph suggests a relationship between the transmission of inequality and intergenerational economic mobility (Corak, 2016); it shows that our estimate is similar to those observed for Italy (0.50) and the United Kingdom (0.5), just above Argentina (0.47) and the United States (0.40), and below Chile (0.52) and Brazil (0.58). Mexico shows a low level of economic intergenerational mobility compared with advanced European economies, although it is reasonable for its level of income inequality. However, among similar economies (Argentina, Chile, Brazil, and Peru), Mexico is the least unequal country and has the second highest level of intergenerational mobility.
This result needs to be interpreted with caution. With the limited available data on earnings, synthetic family earnings are not observed long enough to completely solve the problem of measurement error and attenuation bias (Mazumder, 2005). Better estimates could be computed if data on children and parents were available in the form of surveys or administrative records. However, given the current level of inequality in Mexico, our estimate suggests a reasonable lower bound of intergenerational economic mobility.
4. Conclusion
This study provides different measures for intergenerational economic mobility for Mexico, using earnings as a measure of the extent to which society rewards people’s merit (Mazumder, 2005) in a context of high inequality. It documents three main findings. First, the aggregate IGE estimate for Mexico is around 0.5, which is above the IGE for advanced economies and similar to countries like Argentina and Chile. Second, younger generations are more likely to experience higher degrees of mobility. Although future research needs to validate this finding, and discard it is driven by measurement error. Third, intergenerational variation across regions of birth suggests that people who were born in the southern part of Mexico experience the lowest degree of intergenerational mobility.
Although the estimates are stable to different robustness checks, it is necessary to interpret these results with caution. Our synthetic approach addresses the issue of measurement error by considering multi-year averages of synthetic family earnings by cohort and state of birth (e.g., Antman and McKenzie, 2007), but the available data does not allow us to fully address attenuation bias (Aaronson and Mazumder, 2008; Mazumder, 2005). However, our aggregate IGE estimate is very likely to be an accurate lower bound, and the overall portrait of income inequality in Mexico suggests a rigid society that does not fully compensate people for their effort.
Further research should seek data sources that allow for the comparison of parents’ and children’s earnings and income, examine spatial variation of intergenerational mobility at the most disaggregated level, and deepen its focus on the economic factors influencing intergenerational mobility in Mexico, including investment in human capital, returns to skills, labor market inequalities, and public policy (Corak, 2016; Solon, 2004).