1. Introduction
Power generation is subject to different sources of uncertainty (e.g., changes in fuel and electricity prices, changes in the cost of CO2 emissions, and changes in the interest rate). Therefore, uncertainty exerts a direct impact on the risk-return profiles of the generation of different technologies. In this regard, the Portfolio Theory, developed by Markowitz (1952), has been extensively used to design plans for power generation that reduce risk and increase returns through diversification (see DeLlano-Paz et al. (2017), for a review). However, existing papers do not provide a description on how the authors construct the Efficient Frontier (EF) of the Power Generation Portfolio (PGP) analyzed (e.g., Perea González and Zavaleta Vazquez (2020), Gómez-Ríos and Juárez-Luna (2019), Costa et al. (2017), Pinheiro Neto et al. (2017), Adams and Jamasb (2016), Jain et al. (2014), Cunha and Ferreira (2014), Francés et al. (2013), Losekann et al. (2013), Arnesano et al. (2012), Bhattacharya and Kojima (2012), Allan et al. ( 2011), Delarue et al. (2011), Roques et al. (2010), Vithayasrichareon et al. (2010a), Vithayasrichareon et al. (2010b), Roques et al. (2008), Roques (2006), and Awerbuch and Berger (2003)). The construction of the EF, performed mostly by simulation, remains as a black box.
In the present paper, we aim to open such a black box by providing a detailed methodology for the parametric construction of the EF of PGP of up to five assets.1 Following the existing literature, in the present analysis the EF refers to the set of the PGP that maximize their expected returns for a given level of risk. That is, the expected return of an efficient PGP can be increased only by increasing its risk (Awerbuch and Berger, 2003). The present methodology could also be applied to PGP based on the Levelized Cost of Electricity (LCOE). In such a case, the EF would be a set of PGP that can yield the lowest expected LCOE at given levels of expected risk (Jansen et al., 2006).
The analysis relies on the fact that the risk of the PGP is a convex function of the shares of the different assets. The methodology works as follows: first, obtain the shares of the assets that guarantee the maximal expected return on the PGP. Then, obtain the shares of the assets that guarantee the minimal risk of the PGP. We then formulate the risk of the efficient generation portfolios as a parametric equation of the shares of the assets. Finally, the EF corresponds to the parametric equation of the risk-return profiles from the minimal risk of the PGP to the maximal expected return of the PGP.
The majority of the existing literature on energy portfolios follows a two-step methodology proposed by Roques et al. (2008). In the first step, the distribution of the returns is simulated by applying Monte Carlo simulation or real options theory. In the second step, the portfolio theory is applied to simulated data to find the optimal generation portfolios. In this paper we focus on the second step of such a methodology.
To exemplify the advantages and the scope of the methodology, we apply it to replicating and extending the existing results from the following three papers: Roques et al. (2008), Jain et al. (2014), and Roques et al. (2010). Among the main results, we have the following:
Roques et al. (2008) analyze portfolios of three technologies: CyCle gas turbine (CCGT), coal, and the nuclear plant. These authors conduct the analysis with pairs of technologies under three scenarios as follows: a) no correlation among the prices of electricity, fuel and CO2; 2) there are correlations among the prices of electricity, fuel and CO2, and 3) investors can secure a long-term power purchase agreement. We replicate the results of the second scenario. Our results contradict the following conclusion of Roques et al. (2008): "the optimal portfolio for an investor in this case study is to invest only in CCGTs, as any other portfolio would both reduce returns and increase risk." We find efficient portfolios that assign to CCGT a share less than 100%. Actually, the efficient portfolio of minimal risk and also minimal Expected Net Present Value (ENPV) has the following shares: CCGT 53.7%, nuclear 20.5%, and coal 25.8%.
Jain et al. (2014) analyze portfolios of four types of nuclear reactors: 1) Generic Gen III type Light Water Reactor (LWR); 2) Fast Reactors (FR); 3) High Temperature Reactor (HTR), and 4) Super Critical Water Reactor (SCWR). The analysis was conducted under budget constraint and capacity constraint.2 We replicate the results of the case with budget constraint. The EF we obtain differs considerably from the one obtained by Jain et al. (2014). We find that the portfolio of minimal risk and lower expected return has the following shares: Gen III 18%, HTR 26%, SCWR 25%, and FR 31%. This result contradicts the following conclusion of Jain et al. (2014): "an investor who wants to minimize the uncertainty of returns and is willing to take a lower expected return in order to do so,will choose a portfolio with more Gen IV type reactors [FR 56% and HTR 35%]."
Roques et al. (2010) analyze cross-country portfolios of joint wind production of five European countries (Austria, Denmark, France, Germany, and Spain). The authors utilize two objective functions to define optimal cross-countries wind power portfolios: i) optimizing wind-power output, and ii) maximizing wind-power contribution to system reliability.3 We replicate the results of the first objective function. Our results are considerably different than the ones obtained by Roques et al. (2010). For instance, we find that the efficient portfolio that reaches a Wind Portfolio Capacity Factor (WPCF) of 0.2318 allocates the following weights to the five countries: Spain 30%, Germany 8%, Austria 5%, France 7%, and Denmark 50%. On the other hand, Roques et al. (2010) find that, for the same WPCF level, the efficient portfolio allocates the following weights to the five countries: Spain 54%, Germany 0%, Austria 6%, France 10%, and Denmark 31%. Differences are noteworthy in the weights received by Denmark, Spain, and Germany.
The present methodology has remarkable advantages: 1) it allows to conduct analysis with up to five assets together; 2) it allows to know the shares of the assets for any risk-return profile; 3) the EF is limited by a maximum allowed risk of the PGP; 4) it provides more coherent results than those obtained in the existing literature; 5) it points out that there are optimal investment alternatives that have been denied by previous analysis, and 6) it avoids biases in the design of investment policies in electricity generation. Therefore, the parametric formulation of the EF of the PGP constitutes a powerful tool for both power generation policy-makers and large power companies (in liberalized markets). In addition, the present methodology could be extended to analyze portfolios of more than five asses.
The paper also states that the so-called "portfolio effect" results from the fact that the risk of the PGP is a convex function of the shares of the different assets.
The whole analysis relies on the assumption that the covariances of the returns of the different assets are zero. This strong assumption allows gains in tractability, clarity, and in the scope of the methodology formulated.
To the best of our knowledge, this is the first effort to provide a detailed methodology for the parametric construction of the EF of PGP. It is noteworthy that the present parametric formulation of the EF of PGP could be applied to portfolios based on assets different from those of power-generation technologies.4
The paper is organized as follows: in Section 2, we present the preliminaries; Section 3 presents PGP of 2 and 3 technologies, replicates the results obtained by Roques et al. (2008), and provides the proof of the "portfolio effect." Section 4 presents PGP of 4 nuclear reactors and replicates the results obtained by Jain et al. (2014). Section 5 presents cross-country PGP of 5 countries and replicates the results obtained by Roques et al. (2010). Section 6 contains the final remarks and conclusions. The appendix contains the formal proofs.
2. Preliminaries
We apply the Portfolio Theory developed by Markowitz (1952) to find the efficient power-generation mix: the return of the generation mix
can be increased only by increasing its risk. As customary, risk is measured by the Standard
Deviation (SD) of the returns. Formally, let
Where
Lemma 1 Let
and
where the double summation extends to any values
See pp. 158, Freund et al. (2000).
The first result of Lemma 1 indicates that the expected return of the PGP is a convex sum of the expected returns of the different assets. Following corollary summarizes such a fact:
Corollary 1 Assume that assets are ordered according to their expected
return,
Second result of Lemma 1 indicates that the risk of the PGP depends on two facts of the
different assets, their shares and the covariances of their returns. The risk of the PGP
reduces when the covariances among the returns of the assets are negative. The risk of the
PGP increases when the covariances among the returns of the assets are positive.5 The existing literature reports that,
regardless of the variable used to construct the PGP (NPV, LCOE, capacity factor, or
installed capacity), the covariances amongst the different assets have an absolute value
considerably less than one (e.g., Perea González and Zavaleta Vazquez (2020), Pinheiro Neto et al. (2017), Adams and Jamasb (2016), Cunha and
Ferreira (2014), Roques et al. (2010), and Roques et al. (2008)). As the shares of the assets have values less than one, we expect
the term
Lemma 1 and Corollary 1 provide the tools to construct the EF of the PGP parametrically. The methodology works as follows:
1) Rank the assets according to their expected return,
2) Obtain the shares of the assets,
3) Formulate the risk of the efficient generation portfolios as a parametric equation of the shares of the assets.
4) Finally, the EF corresponds to the parametric equation of the risk-return profiles from the minimal risk of the PGP to the maximal expected return of the PGP.6
Worth noting that, in many cases the EF is not allowed to reach the maximal expected return
of the PGP as it is very risky. Under this scenario, we also need to define a maximal
allowed risk of the PGP,
Now we have all the building blocks to provide a parametric formulation of the EF of PGP. We start with the portfolios of two technologies.
3. Optimal portfolios for electricity generators in the UK electricity market
In this section we replicate the results obtained by Roques et al. (2008). The authors apply portfolio theory to identify the portfolios that maximize the returns of private investors for given risk levels in the UK electricity market. The authors use Monte Carlo simulation to compute the distribution of returns and their correlations. Three technologies are considered: CyCle gas turbine (CCGT), coal, and the nuclear plant. Instead of performing the analysis with the three technologies, these authors work with pairs of plants under three scenarios: 1) no correlation among electricity, fuel and CO2 prices; 2) there are correlations between electricity, fuel and CO2 prices, and 3) investors can secure a long-term power purchase agreement.
We replicate the results of the second scenario in which there are correlations among electricity, fuel, and CO2 prices. Due to expositional motives, we conduct the analysis in two steps. First, as Roques et al. (2008) do, we find the efficient portfolios of two technologies: CCGT and coal. Second, we analyze portfolios including those of the three technologies: CCGT, coal and nuclear.
Data is taken from Roques et al. (2008), Table 4,
2nd scenario (with correlations), page 1839. The returns and risk of the different
generation technologies are given respectively by the ENPV and the SD of the ENPV. The
corresponding ENPV and variance of CCGT (cc), Nuclear (nu) and Coal (co) are:
We proceed to analyze PGP of two technologies.
3.1 Portfolios of two technologies
The risk of the PGP depends on the shares of technologies 1 and 2. The following result provides the shares of technologies 1 and 2 that guarantee the minimal risk of the PGP.
Proposition 1 (Minimal risk of PGP of two technologies)
From
expression (4)
, the risk of a PGP of two technologies is given by
a)
The risk of the PGP, given by
b) The minimal risk of the PGP is
See appendix.
The following result provides the parametric formulation of the EF of PGP of two technologies.
Proposition 2 (EF of PGP of two technologies)
Let
a) The risk of the efficient portfolios is obtained by the shares of technologies 1 and 2, given by the following parametric equation:
where parameter
b)
The risk of the PGP in the EF is given by
c)
The maximal expected return for each corresponding level of risk is given
by
See appendix.
We now have the theoretical tools to analyze the PGP of CCGT and Coal.
3.1.1 Efficient portfolios of CCGT-Coal
Following Proposition 2, CCGT corresponds to technology 1 and Coal to technology 2. Then, from Proposition 1, the shares of the technologies that ensure the minimal risk of the PGP are
The minimal risk reached by this PGP is
From Proposition 2, the risk of the efficient portfolios is obtained by the shares of technologies 1 and 2, given by the following parametric equation:
for
The parameters of the EF are presented in the following figure:
Although CCGT strongly dominates the PGP, there are efficient portfolios that assign to
CCGT a share less than 100%, which reduce return but also reduce risk. Therefore, CCGT
receives a share of 68% in the efficient portfolio of minimal risk and also minimal
ENPV. This result contradicts the following conclusion of Roques et al. (2008): "The optimal portfolio for an investor in this
case study is to invest only in CCGTs, as any other portfolio would both reduce returns
and increase risk." In fact, even devoting a share of 100% to CCGT constitutes an
efficient portfolio, an economy would face a potential social risk by placing its power
generation in one single technology. Thus a decision-maker might support diversification
by, for example, allowing the PGP to reach a risk of
We straightforwardly extend the analysis to the remaining pairs of technologies: CCGT-Nuclear and Nuclear-coal. Following subsection present the EF of every pair of technologies. The corresponding analysis will be provided upon request.
It is noteworthy that the present analysis is incomplete, in that it does not include nuclear plants. The following subsection reveals that introducing nuclear plants changes the shares of the technologies in the efficient portfolios. We now proceed to analyze PGP of three technologies.
3.2 Portfolios of three technologies
The following result provides the shares of technologies 1, 2, and 3, which guarantee the minimum risk of the PGP.
Proposition 3 (Minimal risk of PGP of three technologies)
From
expression (4)
, the risk of the PGP of three technologies is given by
a)
The risk of the PGP, given by
where
b) The minimal risk of the PGP is
See appendix.
The following result provides the parametric formulation of the EF for PGP of three technologies.
Proposition 4 (EF of PGP of three technologies)
Let
a) The risk of the efficient portfolios is obtained by the shares of technologies 1, 2, and 3, given by the following parametric equation:
where parameter
b) The risk of the PGP in the EF is given by
for
c)
The maximal expected return for each corresponding level of risk is given
by
See appendix.
We now have the tools to analyze the PGP of CCGT-Nuclear-Coal.
3.2.1 Efficient portfolios of CCGT-Nuclear-Coal
Following Proposition 4, CCGT, nuclear and coal correspond respectively to technologies 1, 2 and 3. Then, from Proposition 3, the shares of the technologies that ensure the minimal risk of the PGP are
The minimal risk reached by this PGP is
From Proposition 4, we obtain
and
for
The triangle in Figure 3 resembles the triangle of the left side of Figure 2, page 841, in Roques et al. (2008). However, alike the triangle in Roques et al. (2008), we include the PGP of minimal risk for each pair of technologies. The parameters of the EF of the PGP are presented in figure 4.
We find that, although CCGT strongly dominates the PGP, there are efficient portfolios
that assign to CCGT a share less than 100%, that reduce return but also reduce risk. In
fact, the efficient portfolio of minimal risk and also minimal ENPV has the following
shares: CCGT 53.7%, nuclear 20.5%, and coal 25.8%. This result contradicts the following
conclusion of Roques et al. (2008): "The optimal
portfolio for an investor in this case study is to invest only in CCGTs, as any other
portfolio would both reduce returns and increase risk." Again, a decision-maker might
support diversification by, for example, allowing the PGP to reach a risk of
The present methodology permits the analysis of the PGP of three technologies,
providing the shares of the technologies for any risk-return profile in the EF. Thus,
there is no need to apply any mean-variance utility function, as Roques et al. (2008) do, in order to find efficient portfolios for
certain levels of risk aversion. Actually, it would be straightforward to verify that
the mean-variance utility function used by Roques et al. (2008) reaches its maximum at the efficient portfolio
of minimal risk and also minimal ENPV (
3.3 The portfolio effect
It is worth noting that the minimal risk of the PGP of CCGT-coal is
Proposition 5 (Portfolio effect)
Let
See appendix.
The previous result states that there is no need to include a risk-free asset to reduce the risk of a PGP, as argued by Awerbuch and Berger (2003).
Thus, from Proposition 5, we conclude that the results obtained by Roques et al. (2008) are incomplete, in that they were derived by analyzing only pairs of the three available technologies. Therefore, their conclusions create a bias in the design of investment policies in electricity generation.8
4. Nuclear reactor generation portfolios
In this section we replicate the results obtained by Jain et al. (2014). The authors apply analyze portfolios of nuclear reactors that maximize the returns for given risk levels. They use real options to compute the distribution of the returns. The following four types of nuclear reactors were considered for the portfolio: 1) Generic Gen III type Light Water Reactor (LWR); 2) Fast Reactors (FR); 3) High Temperature Reactor (HTR), and 4) Super Critical Water Reactor (SCWR). The analysis was conducted under budget constraint and capacity constraint. In this section, we replicate the results of the case with budget constraint.
The risk of the portfolio depends on the shares of reactors 1, 2, 3 and 4. The following result provides the shares of reactors 1, 2, 3 and 4 that guarantee the minimal risk of the PGP.
Proposition 6 (Minimal risk of PGP of four reactors)
From
expression (4)
, the risk of the PGP of four reactors is given by
a)
The risk of the PGP,
where
b) The minimal risk of the PGP is
See appendix.
The following result provides the parametric formulation of the efficient frontier for PGP of four reactors.
Proposition 7 (EF of PGP of four reactors)
Let
a) The risk of the efficient portfolios is obtained by the shares of reactors 1, 2, 3 and 4, given by the following parametric equation:
where parameter
b) The risk of the PGP in the EF is given by
for
c) The maximal expected return for every corresponding level of risk is given by
for
See appendix.
We already have the theoretical tools to replicate the results obtained by Jain et al.
(2014) for the nuclear portfolio of Gen
III-HTR-SCWR-FR, under budget constraint. Data is taken from Jain et al.
(2014), Table 11, page 108. The expected returns
and variance of reactors Gen III, HTR, SCWR and FR are, respectively:
Following Proposition 7, Gen III, HTR, SCWR, and FR correspond, respectively, to reactors 1, 2, 3, and 4. Thus, from Proposition 6, the shares of the four reactors that ensure the minimal risk are
The minimal risk reached by this PGP is
Following Proposition 7, we obtain
and
for
The following figure presents the parameters of the EF. The proposed EF ranges from 1 to 10. Notwithstanding this, we present all of the efficient portfolios in order to compare them with those obtained by Jain et al. (2014), shown in figure 7b (page 108).
We find that an investor who wants to minimize risk with a lower expected return will chose a portfolio with following shares: Gen III 18%, HTR 26%, SCWR 25%, and FR 31%. This result contradicts the following conclusion of Jain et al. (2014): "An investor who wants to minimize the uncertainty of returns and is willing to take a lower expected return in order to do so,will choose a portfolio with more Gen IV type reactors [FR 56% and HTR 35%]." Our EF differs considerably from that obtained by Jain et al. (2014). For example, Jain et al. (2014) state, in figure 7, that the efficient portfolio that reaches an expected return of 1.2, allocates to reactors Gen III and HTR a share of around 50%. The present analysis indicates that, for such an expected return, the shares of the four reactors are: Gen III 67%, HTR 16%, SCWR 14%, and FR 3%. We find our results more coherent than those obtained by Jain et al. (2014).
When replicating the case under capacity constraint, we also find different results from
those of Jain et al. (2014). For example, Jain
et al. (2014) state, in figure 8, that the efficient portfolio of minimum risk (
It is noteworthy that the difference in the results creates a bias in the design of investment policies in electricity generation by nuclear reactors.
Jain et al. (2014) also test the sensitivity of the portfolio under three different scenarios: 1) varying discount rates; 2) varying electricity price growth rates, and 3) varying uncertainties in electricity prices. However, they do not provide the statistics of the returns for such scenarios. The present methodology could be applied to replicate the results of such scenarios if the statistics of the returns were available.
5. Optimal portfolios of wind-power in Europe
In this section, we replicate the results obtained by Roques et al. (2010). These authors use historical wind-production data from five European countries (Austria, Denmark, France, Germany, and Spain) to identify cross-country portfolios that minimize the risk of joint wind production for a given level of production. They employ two objective functions to define optimal cross-country wind power portfolios: i) optimizing wind-power output, and ii) maximizing wind-power contribution to system reliability. In this section, we replicate the results of the first case.
The risk of the portfolio depends on the weight received by the wind production of countries 1, 2, 3, 4, and 5. The following result provides the weights received by countries 1, 2, 3, 4, and 5 that guarantee the minimal risk of the PGP.
Proposition 8 (Minimal risk of PGP of five countries)
From
expression (4)
, the risk of the PGP of five countries is given by
a)
The risk of the PGP,
where
b) The minimal risk of the PGP is
See appendix.
Following result provides the parametric formulation of the EF of PGP of cross-country wind power.
Proposition 9 (EF of PGP of five countries)
Let
a) The risk of the efficient portfolios is obtained by the weight received by the wind production of countries 1, 2, 3, 4 and 5, given by the following parametric equation:
where the parameter
Let
b) The risk of the PGP in the EF is given by
for
c) The maximal expected return for every corresponding level of risk is given by
for
See appendix.
We now possessed the theoretical tools to replicate the results obtained by Roques et al.
(2010) for the wind portfolios of
Denmark-Austria-Spain-France-Germany under the case optimizing wind power output. Data is
taken from Roques et al. (2010),
Table 5, page 3250. For these the returns and the risk of the different countries are given
by the wind-power capacity factors (WPCF) and their SD. The corresponding expected returns
and variance of Denmark, Austria, Spain, France, and Germany are:
From Proposition 9, countries 1, 2, 3, 4, and 5 correspond, respectively, to Denmark, Austria, Spain, France, and Germany. Thus, from Proposition 8, the weights received by the wind production of the countries that ensure the minimal risk are
The minimal risk of this PGP is given by
From Proposition 9, we obtain
and
for
The following figure presents the parameters of the EF. The proposed EF ranges from 1 to 8. However, we present all of the efficient portfolios in order to compare them with those obtained by Roques et al. (2010), shown in figure 4 (page 3251).
We obtain a very different EF from that obtained by Roques et al. (2010). For example, we find that the efficient portfolio that reach a WPCF of 0.2318 allocates the following weights to the five countries: Spain 30%, Germany 8%, Austria 5%, France 7%, and Denmark 50%.On the other hand, Roques et al. (2010) find that, for the same level of WPCF, the efficient portfolio allocates the following weights to the five countries: Spain 54%, Germany 0%, Austria 6%, France 10%, and Denmark 31%. The differences are noteworthy in the weights received by Denmark, Spain, and Germany. In our analysis, Germany receives a weight greater than zero while the weights received by Denmark and Spain are nearly switched between each other in the paper by Roques et al. (2010).
We find our results more coherent than those obtained by Roques et al. (2010). To see this, recall the fact that the expected return of the PGP is a convex sum of the expected returns of the different assets. Thus, as the WPCF of 0.2318 is closer to the expected return of Denmark and above the expected return of Spain, we expect that Denmark should receive a greater weight than Spain in the PGP. Which hold in our analysis as the grater weight received by Spain is 33%.
When replicating the case of maximizing the wind-power contribution to the reliability of the system, we also find different results from those of Roques et al. (2010). Unlike these authors, we find that Germany receives a weight greater than zero and up to 15% in the PGP (This case will be provided upon request).
Notably, the difference in the results creates a bias in the design of policies in electricity generation by cross-country wind-power.
Roques et al. (2010) also find the EF of "constrained" portfolios. These authors consider two types of constraints: 1)wind resource potential constraints, and 2) network limitations constraints. However, they do not provide the statistics of the returns for each scenario. The present methodology could be applied to replicate the results of such scenarios if the statistics of the returns were available.
6. Final remarks and conclusions
The present paper tackles the problem of the diversification of energy generation by providing a methodology to construct parametrically the EF of PGP for up to five assets. The methodology was applied to replicate and extend the results of the following three papers: Roques et al. (2008), Jain et al. (2014), and Roques et al. (2010). The present methodology has remarkable advantages:
It allows to conduct analysis with up to five assets together.
It allows to know the shares of the assets for any risk-return profile.
The EF could be limited by a maximum allowed risk of the PGP.
It provides more coherent results than those obtained in the existing literature.
It points out that there are optimal investment alternatives that have been denied by previous analysis.
It avoids biases in the design of investment policies in electricity generation.
Thus, the parametric formulation of PGP proved to be a powerful tool for power generation policy-makers or investors. In fact, it could be applied to portfolios of assets different than those of power-generation technologies.
From the structure of the paper, it would be straight forward to extend the methodology to obtaining the shares of assets in order to guarantee the minimal risk of PGP of more than five assets. However, the corresponding mathematical proofs must be performed to construct the EF of PGP parametrically of more than five assets.
Complete analysis relies on the assumption that the covariances of the returns amongst the different assets is zero. Depending on computational availability, future research could be extended to verify the actual effect of the correlations of the returns on the minimal risk of the portfolio.