1. Introduction
In modern societies, almost the entire money in the economy is created by banks issuing credit to households and businesses. Banks offer loans to the public using the deposits they have as liabilities. The creation of credit is very important to fuel technological and economic progress. Credit creation gives us the opportunity to bring forward ideas and innovations, to create profits and accumulate capital. It is thanks to credit that we can bring future income to work and create wealth, and set new income paths that will increase the next generation’s welfare. The amount of bank credit in the economy represents the availability of working capital for businesses, and the more expensive it becomes, the more difficult it is to make businesses profitable and increase economic growth in general.
If, for some reason, some entrepreneurs cannot get bank loans at a given interest rate, we say that there is credit rationing. From a classical perspective, this is a contradiction because we were thought that at an equilibrium price markets would clear and there would be no unsatisfied demand. Certainly, asymmetric information and moral hazard may play an important role in why banks do not want to lend money to some enterprises or give them less than they require. But there are other reasons why credit rationing exists. In this paper we explore institutional parameters such as judiciary efficiency and criminality as the cause of credit rationing.
Jaffee and Russell (1976) is one of the first works to explain credit rationing as a product of asymmetric information, specifically adverse selection. They explained that there are honest and dishonest borrowers. The first type will borrow what they can repay and the second type will default at the minimum cost. In their model, a market equilibrium is divided into two scenarios. In the first, all borrowers are rationed and, in the second, some will be left out of the market after making short-run gains. Perhaps one influential work about credit rationing is (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981). This work explains credit rationing as an adverse selection problem. Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) built a model which explains that banks will separate high risk borrowers using the interest rate. Individuals who are willing to pay a high interest rate are those with the highest probability of default. So, credit will be rationed to those that are willing to pay after a threshold interest rate because it is more plausible that their projects are riskier with a high probability to fail. They accept that excess demand is compatible with an equilibrium rate. Rising interest or increasing collateral may not be a solution because the chances of default increase and the profitability for the banks decreases. However, the solution is to limit the number of loans available.
Another important work on credit rationing is (Jappelli et al., 2005) which introduces institutional variables in the analysis. (Jappelli et al., 2005) explains credit rationing as a result of judiciary inefficiency. They argue that courts may fail to enforce full repayment to banks when borrowers suddenly default. Borrowers might be tempted to default or retain part of the collateral. This may encourage banks to reduce credit. (Safavian and Sharma, 2007) is an empirical analysis that confirms that judiciary efficiency is important for financial markets. They implemented regression analysis to observe how lending is affected by courts' performance. They found that more efficient and speedy courts may improve bank lending, though the important variable might be enforcement of the laws. (Moro et al., 2018) and (Moro et al., 2018) are two empirical works that use regression analysis to prove that efficient courts and property rights protection improves bank lending.
(Hernández and Villagómez, 2013) gives an overview of the Mexican Financial System and introduces the topic of property rights. They point out the importance of judicial efficiency in Mexico despite the fact that there is poor performance in the execution of contracts compared with other countries. Another work that focuses on judiciary efficiency is (Laeven and Majnoni, 2005), which uses cross-section analysis to study the effect of the judiciary's performance on interest rate spreads across countries. They found that courts’ efficiency is important to decrease financial costs. (La Porta et al., 2003) analyses related lending in Mexico, where banks lend to enterprises where shareholders have a special interest or have some ownership. They discovered that these enterprises usually perform poorly despite borrowing at a lower interest rate, following an extraction pattern similar to looting. (La Porta et al., 2001) is a work that analyses shareholder protection in the French and British judicial systems. They constructed a panel with 49 countries and analyzed the risks of ownership for shareholders and creditors.
Before we proceed to our study, we must clarify the scientific purpose of this research. We are trying to indirectly analyze the effect of some institutional variables that affect property rights, something that has already been advanced theoretically and empirically in some respects. For example, most of the literature points out the importance of the judiciary in protecting banks' collateral when default occurs. These studies explain that credit rationing may increase if the judiciary is inefficient at protecting banks’ interests and collateral. Of course, courts also protect other property rights such as profits and returns to businesses and investors. Some authors like (Alchian, 1965) and (Alchian and Demsetz, 1973) state that property rights come from societies’ etiquette, social customs and exclusion as well as the enforcement of laws by authorities. It has been noted that developed or high-income countries have a high degree of protection of property rights, with well defined social customs and law enforcement. But many developing countries lack the institutional framework to enforce property laws. Sometimes property rights are not well defined and, in most cases, these developing countries suffer from severe internal conflicts such as widespread criminality, civil wars, and other low-intensity conflicts. In some, there is no central authority that can provide for public safety and enforce the rule of law. In this respect, we decided to approach credit rationing by including criminality as an important variable that effectively decreases appropriations by businesses and households. Crime is an important variable that prevents material development and restricts individuals’ functionings. The current literature explains judicial inefficiency as a variable that affects banks from recovering collateral. But criminality directly affects enterprises by extracting investment, capital and profits that otherwise may be used for investment. Furthermore, the level of criminality is affected by police performance, which is under direct jurisdiction of executive powers and usually those in charge of fiscal budgeting.
The first part of the paper is an introduction with some relevant literature on the topic of credit rationing. The second part contains a theoretical framework to describe the behavior of banks, entrepreneurs and government debt. The third part of the paper contains the empirical analysis and the final part contains the conclusions.
2. Theoretical model
2.1 The bank
We built a simplified model of credit rationing which explains the problem of
credit contracts under incomplete property rights caused by judicial
inefficiency and criminal extraction. We built our model based on (Jappelli et al., 2005) using the similar
treatment of judicial inefficiency but we added an extraction parameter in order
to simulate entrepreneur’s low appropriation of wealth. (Jappelli et al., 2005) explained that the important
function of courts is to force borrowers to repay their bank loans when they
default. So the judiciary’s efficiency parameter
Additionally, we introduce a parameter
Under the assumption of competitive financial markets with risk neutral banks, similarly as in (Jappelli et al., 2005), the opportunity cost of raising funds for bank loans is:
Where
Which can also express the total amount of collateral required by the bank to recover its loan in case of default:
When there are perfect police enforcement and efficient judiciary
2.2 The entrepreneur
Let us now consider a borrower with a Von Newmann type utility function. Let us
also assume that the individual can affect the probability of success
The first order condition of this problem is:
In this problem, the borrower's optimal collateral is:
From these results we observe that the entrepreneur's collateral is less than the
collateral required by the bank
2.3 The credit contract
In order to write down a credit contract, the bank will require that the entrepreneur commit to a certain level of collateral. In our analysis, the collateral requested would be:
In the scenario of judiciary efficiency and public safety
But in our world there is judicial inefficiency
There are some actions the bank may take in order to improve its position. One thing might be to avoid doing business in rural and isolated areas where criminality is high, and to limit operations in towns and cities where the judiciary is famous for being incompetent. Another thing the bank may do is to separate those entrepreneurs into two types: A first group of entrepreneurs that have enough power to protect their wealth and possessions, and a second group that is weak and cannot protect their businesses. Only those politically connected, powerful and influential people will receive credit, while those who do not have enough strength to protect their wealth will be rationed.
This sorting is not an easy task as it may sound. This sorting mechanism seems to
be a problem of adverse selection, where individuals willing to
pay a high interest rate
But in reality, even if
2.4 Private savings
Consider now the individual’s decision on his portfolio of savings. If the individual is not an entrepreneur, he/she must decide either to lend his money to private entrepreneurs or to the Government. His consumption when young and when old are:
Where
But under this condition, the intitutional parameters
One way to determine the optimal amount of private lending and government bonds is to construct an optimal portfolio where overall returns are maximized subjected to a level of systemic risk. Let be the aggregate optimal two-assets portfolio be:
Where
We must also mention that banks in Mexico avoid high-risk investments usually under prudential regulation. Safe and sound investments are required and government bonds are in a strong position in the bank's assets. For example, the Mexican Pension Funds (AFORE) are limited in their ability to invest in risky stocks in national and international markets. In this form, regulators may indirectly have a say in the allocation of credit to the public sector. Because the banking system is regulated, federal agencies may benefit from larger bank investments and loans. However, in this paper we explore the position of local governments rather than federal agencies.
2.5 Public debt financing
Since the start of this century and before law of Financial Discipline for States
and Municipalities of 2016, banks increased lending to state governments and
Municipalities in Mexico. During this period of increasing local government
debt, the parameters
In an economy where macroeconomic stabilization is done by the monetary
authorities, governments and public companies are left to decide by themselves
the way they are going to manage their fiscal deficit. The government usually
cooperates with monetary authorities in order to set up macroeconomic objectives
such as inflation, interest rates, economic growth rate, public debt and
deficit, among other variables. But sometimes they are left free to manage the
government deficit using debt financing through bonds and direct borrowing at
some level. Let us assume now that the banks will channel the rationed credit
into direct loans to the public sector, which is considered a safe borrower. The
total credit
We are now only interested in the public debt and assume that debt financing is
done through direct loans from banking institutions to the Government and other
public enterprises1. The
outstanding public debt
Where
In this equation we observe that the cost of servicing the public debt increases
well above the interest rate
Here the term
Where
And the solution to this equation is:
Where
2.6 Stability of public Debt
Let us first assume an initial scenario where the macroeconomic situation is of
high interest rates, low judiciary quality, high criminality and low economic
growth
Now let us imagine the other possible scenario where the interest rate is low,
the judiciary is more efficient, criminality is low and economic growth is
relatively high
Although the Central Bank has a say in the stability of the interest rates, we
know that only the government can influence the levels of
Additionally, if the government makes additional efforts to enforce fiscal
discipline and eliminate the primary deficit over time, say
3. Empirical analysis
3.1 Data
In Mexico, only the Federal Government can issue bonds, although in very few cases local governments are allowed to issue debt on the financial markets. During the 2000’s and 2010’s the usual way to finance local government deficits was direct borrowing from commercial banks. Using state level data in order to analyze state government debt is one possible way to measure the effect of institutional variables and credit rationing. The amount of bank credit for the public sector has increased steadily since NAFTA was signed in 1994. Bank credit to state governments increased during the period of 1994 to 2005, perhaps because the amount of credit to the industry decreased and also because of federal regulations. After 2005 the amount of credit to industry recovered but stalled with the financial crisis of 2008. During the financial crisis of 2008 bank credit to the industry did not grow but bank loans to state governments more than doubled. We must also recall that this period was also important in terms of large gains from oil revenue. Despite unexpected and additional fiscal revenues, bank credit to the states increased at a similar rate compared to the industry. From the period 2008 to 2016 the bank credit to state governments had similar growth to that of the industry sector until Federal regulators issued laws to limit government borrowing. The figure 1 shows the relative growth of bank credit for the industry and the state governments.
The theoretical analysis implies that at least some of the rationed credit will be redirected to the public sector. We decided to approach the effect of credit rationing on public debt using aggregate state-level data. We decided to use the amount of direct bank lending to state governments as the dependent variable, using data provided by the Central Bank of Mexico (Banxico). Information about criminality was obtained from the Mexican National Security Council, which is an intergovernmental organization that over- sees the national security policy. Information about courts' efficiency was collected from the Federal Judicial Council (Consejo de la Judicatura Federal) which is the management branch overseeing all federal courts in Mexico. Data on bank defaults in the industrial sector was obtained from Banxico and used as a proxy for credit rationing. The tertiary-education graduation ratio was used to control for the demand for public goods, as tertiary education has an important effect on household income and intergenerational transfers. We constructed a panel for 32 states and for a period of 13 years, from 2004 to 2016. We chose this period because of the favorable economic conditions in the economy due to the high price of oil until the new Law of Financial Discipline for Federal Entities and Municipalities was issued in 2016. In order to account for systematic risk, we included a price variable like the Interbank Interest Rate (TIIE) for a 91-day term, which is also provided by Banxico. Rather than using daily or 28 days rates, the 91 term rate captures better the systematic risks in the economy.
3.2 Panel regression
We want to estimate the effect of credit rationing on government borrowing in the presence of low judicial quality and lack of safety for entrepreneurs. The theoretical model implies that credit rationing produces higher levels of state government's debt. We may think of government debt as a function of aggregate income and private lending:
The variable
We expect that public debt will be high when institutional parameters are low
Most variables are in logarithms, previously deflacted by a price index with a
2018 base.
An alternative model combines the institutional parameters as an interactive
variable
Here we espect that
Bank credit to States | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Fixed Model 1 | Fixed Model 2 | Random Model 1 | Random Model 2 | |
lnGDP | −4.622*** | −4.489*** | −0.108 | 0.013 |
(0.902) | (0.891) | (0.316) | (0.302) | |
lnCrime | 0.48** | 0.728*** | ||
(0.245) | (0.2) | |||
lnCourts | 0.215* | 0.398*** | ||
(0.12) | (0.115) | |||
ln(Crime*Courts) | 0.117*** | 0.214*** | ||
(0.046) | (0.039) | |||
Tertiary Educ. | 1.481* | 1.542** | 1.434* | 1.486** |
(0.773) | (0.769) | (0.756) | (0.755) | |
lnDefault | 0.154** | 0.155** | 0.224*** | 0.229*** |
(0.064) | (0.064) | (0.063) | (0.063) | |
TIIE91 | −1.806 | −2.353 | −7.28*** | −7.908*** |
(2.163) | (2.085) | (1.919) | (1.866) | |
Constant | 25.433*** | 25.436*** | −1.661 | −1.607 |
(5.197) | (5.281) | (1.731) | (1.714) | |
Observations | 416 | 416 | 416 | 416 |
R2 Withing | 0.285 | 0.283 | 0.233 | 0.232 |
R2 Between | 0.262 | 0.285 | 0.592 | 0.592 |
R2 Overall | 0.116 | 0.128 | 0.467 | 0.463 |
Note: ∗ p<0.1; ∗∗p <0.05; ∗∗∗p <0.01; N=32, T=13 (2004-2016).
Standard errors in parenthesis. Hausman test rejects H0 of inconsistency. Fixed effects are preferred
Because this analysis is about the supply of bank loans to state government, we
may also be confronted with the possibility of endogenity. We decided to perform
a panel Instrumental Variable (IV) regression in order to account for
endogeneity. Table 2 shows the results
for the IV panel regressions and confirms the results found in the previous
Fixed and Random effects regressions. The Hausman test confirms that IV random
effects are the best estimates in our analysis. The estimate for the interest
rate variable
Bank credit to States | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
IV FE Model 1 | IV FE Model 2 | IV RE Model 1 | IV RE Model 2 | |
lnGDP | −3.571*** | −3.415*** | −0.039 | 0.153 |
(1.145) | (1.081) | (0.333) | (0.312) | |
lnCrime | 0.385 | 0.66*** | ||
(0.254) | (0.205) | |||
lnCourts | 0.261** | 0.413*** | ||
(0.13) | (0.118) | |||
ln(Crime*Courts) | 0.126*** | 0.211*** | ||
(0.047) | (0.04) | |||
lnDefault | 0.138** | 0.134** | 0.202*** | 0.196*** |
(0.069) | (0.068) | (0.072) | (0.072) | |
TIIE91 | −7.561** | −8.208*** | −11.54*** | −12.565*** |
(3.421) | (3.042) | (2.714) | (2.501) | |
Constant | 21.073*** | 20.565*** | −1.031 | −1.063 |
(6.371) | (6.255) | (1.608) | (1.595) | |
Observations | 416 | 416 | 416 | 416 |
R2 Withing | 0.268 | 0.265 | 0.222 | 0.219 |
R2 Between | 0.239 | 0.25 | 0.614 | 0.611 |
R2 Overall | 0.086 | 0.088 | 0.473 | 0.466 |
Note: ∗ p<0.1; ∗∗p <0.05; ∗∗∗p <0.01; N=32, T=13 (2004-2016)
Standard errors in parenthesis.Hausman test cannot reject H0 of inconsistency. Random effects are preferred.
3.3 ARDL regression
We also run a Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) model using
the Pooled Mean Group (PMG) technique. This regression does not fix short-term
estimates across groups but constrains the long-run estimates to be the same
across groups, and also corrects the endogenous regressors problem. Using this
model we may capture the effect of long term growth rates of independent
variables during the period of analysis, which is an important information
considering that we are analysing the dynamic aspects of public debt. Before we
run this model we performed a Levin, Lin, Chu Unit root test and found that all
variables were stationary at I(0) not I(1). However, this first generation test
does not consider cross-sectional dependency. We performed a Pesaran
Cross-sectional Augmented Dickey-Fuller (CADF) test and found that the tertiary
education variable may not be estationary, so we changed the variable and used
the logarithm of tertiary education rate which resulted to be stationary. We
also performed a Pedroni test to ensure that all variables are cointegrated at
least at I(1). The long terms growth rates are shown in Table 3, where the
Bank credit to States | ||
---|---|---|
PMG A | PMG B | |
lnGDPpc | −1.949*** | −1.566*** |
(0.287) | (0.231) | |
lnCrime | 0.044 | |
(0.074) | ||
lnCourts | 0.104** | |
(0.048) | ||
ln(Crime*Courts) | 0.057*** | |
(0.018) | ||
lnTertiary | −0.709** | 0.613* |
(0.296) | (0.323) | |
lnDefatult | 0.191*** | 0.127*** |
(0.025) | (0.027) |
Note: ∗ p<0.1; ∗∗ p<0.05; ∗∗∗ p<0.01.
Standard errors in parenthesis.
3.4 Clustering Analysis
Additionally, we use Cluster analysis, which is a Machine Learning algorithm that
does not require supervision. The idea is to observe for states that may be
similar in terms of debt, credit rationing and institutional parameters. We use
a KMeans algorithm which minimizes the total within-cluster variation to obtain
Where
We performed Hierarquical Cluster Analysis in order to construct groups using a
different algorithm and added another cluster to capture additional information.
This method uses the nearest neighbor algorithm to classify
data and determine how close or far is a point from other points in a
4. Conclusions
In this analysis we used institutional variables to explain credit rationing and also argued that banks were redirecting credit to state governments. We also argue that the public sector may be benefiting when institutional variables are of low quality, therefore there is little incentive to improve them. We also argue that not only protection of banks or creditors is important, but protection of businesses from extraction of their income and property. As in some other studies, judicial efficiency and protection of creditors are important variables that affect credit supply, but we also argue that protection of property and income of households and businesses is also be important.
With respect to the relationship between credit rationing and the public sector, we performed a panel analysis on bank loans to state governments during the period 2004 to 2016. We use loan defaults in the industry sector as a proxy for credit rationing assuming banks reduce the supply of loans to entrepreneurs when defaults are high. Interestingly, when the defaults on industry loans are high, the amount of bank loans to the states increase. The estimates we obtained in all our models seem to confirm this fact.
We also found that crime, as a proxy of extraction of assets and income, is also statistically significant in determining the level of bank loans to the state governments. We also confirmed that the efficiency of courts might also be an important factor that induces a higher supply of loans to state governments. In our analysis, the interaction between judiciary inefficiency and criminality is statistically significant, as shown in our interactive term. Our regression analysis confirms that credit rationing, and intuitional variables such as judiciary inefficiency and criminality induced higher State debt during the period before the enforcement of the law of Financial Discipline for States and Municipalities.
The clustering analysis allows us to observe differences among states in terms of state government borrowing, bank defaults, crime and courts efficiency for the year 2016. This analysis helps us to observe which states are highly indebted, those that have high default levels, and those with high crime and judicial inefficiency. For example, Mexico City seems to be an outlier with highly indebted and high default amounts in per capita terms, and also high crime and average judicial efficiency. On the other hand, Campeche seems to be the state with a much better economic position, low debt per capita and high institutional quality.
In summary, bank loans to the public sector are facilitated because of credit rationing in the private sector. If there are little prospects for private projects, lending to the public sector becomes attractive (e.g. during the 2008 financial crisis). Furthermore, because of the fact that there is high extraction due to crime and scant creditors’ protection (courts’ inefficiency), there is more than an incentive from banks to lend money to local governments. However, this borrowing practice has some unintended consequences. The first one may be that governments might not be induced to improve institutional quality. The second is that higher borrowing by the public sector, without any clear economic plan or goal, might be unsustainable in the long run; which is the reason why the law of fiscal discipline was created.
Additionally, lending to the government, although an easy alternative, has more drawbacks. Because of the crowding out effect on private investment, the probability of successful projects may be limited in a loans market which is already rationed. So we expect that economic growth rate may be affected by higher government expenditure if the public investment multiplier is too low. If we add the judiciary inefficiency and high extraction, then we not only expect credit rationing but also unstable public debt levels over time, making it more difficult to have economic growth.
So it is in the best interest of entrepreneurs, banks and the government that these
two parameters