SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.13 número1Política pública en materia de desarrollo social mediante el Fondo de Infraestructura Social Municipal PotosinoAnálisis de la relación de causalidad entre el índice de precios del productor y del consumidor incorporando variables que capturan el mecanismo de transmisión monetaria: El caso de los países miembros del TLCAN índice de autoresíndice de materiabúsqueda de artículos
Home Pagelista alfabética de revistas  

Servicios Personalizados

Revista

Articulo

Indicadores

Links relacionados

  • No hay artículos similaresSimilares en SciELO

Compartir


EconoQuantum

versión On-line ISSN 2007-9869versión impresa ISSN 1870-6622

EconoQuantum vol.13 no.1 Zapopan ene./jun. 2016

 

Artículos

The gender wage gap and occupational segregation in the Mexican labour market

Pedro Orraca1 

Francisco-Javier Cabrera2 

Gustavo Iriarte3 

1Department of Economics. University of Sussex. Reino Unido. E-mail: p.orraca-romano@sussex.ac.uk

2División de Administración Pública. Centro de Investigación y Docencia Económicas A. C.. México. E-mail: francisco.cabrera@cide.edu

3Department of Economics. University of Sussex. Reino Unido. E-mail: c.iriarte-rivas@sussex.ac.uk


Abstract

This study examines the role of occupational segregation in explaining the gender wage gap in Mexico. Using census data and based on the Brown et al. (1980) decomposition, it is observed that male-female wage differentials increased between 2000 and 2010. For both years, within occupation wage differentials generally increased the gender wage gap, whereas between occupation wage differentials provided the opposite effect. Since within occupation wage differentials are driven by the unexplained component, the results suggest that the gender wage gap is primarily a product of differences in the average returns to productivity related characteristics within occupations. Occupational segregation does not increase male-female wage differentials since women do not appear to encounter barriers into high paying occupations. This result is robust to the use of different levels of occupational aggregation and when correcting the wage equations for selectivity-bias.

Keywords: Occupational segregation; gender wage differentials; Mexico

JEL Classification: J31; J24; J71

Resumen

Este estudio examina el papel que desempeña la segregación ocupacional sobre la brecha salarial de género en México. Mediante información censal y con base en la descomposición propuesta por Brown et al. (1980), se observa que la brecha salarial de género se incrementó entre 2000 y 2010. Las diferencias salariales dentro de las ocupaciones tienden a incrementar la brecha salarial total, mientras que las diferencias salariales entre ocupaciones presentan el efecto opuesto. Dado que las diferencias salariales dentro de las ocupaciones son producto del componente no explicado, los resultados sugieren que la brecha salarial es primordialmente producto de diferencias en el rendimiento de las características productivas de los trabajadores. La segregación ocupacional no incrementa la brecha salarial dado que las mujeres no enfrentan barreras para acceder a ocupaciones altamente remuneradas. Este resultado es robusto al uso de distintos niveles de agregación ocupacional y a la corrección por sesgo de auto-selección.

Palabras clave: Segregación ocupacional; diferencias salariales de género; México

Clasificación JEL: J31; J24; J71

Introduction

In recent decades, due to a series of factors including demographic and cultural changes, an opening of its economy, a rise in the levels of formal education, the implementation of structural reforms which restructured the country’s economy towards a more service oriented one, and a series of crises that pushed women into the labour force, among others, female participation rates in Mexico have substantially increased.

According to information from Mexico’s population censuses, the percentage of women between 18 and 65 years of age participating in the labour force grew from 19.4% in 1970, to 24.2% in 1990 and to 42.3% in 2010. Consequently, analysis of the gender wage gap have become increasingly important, where a large number of studies have examined the evolution of male-female wage differentials in Mexico (e.g. Alarcón and McKinley, 1994; Pagán and Ullibarri, 2000; Popli, 2013). The rise in female labour participation rates has been accompanied by constant changes in the country’s occupational structure and distribution of wages between occupations (see, e.g. Brown, Pagán and Rodríguez-Oreggia, 1999; Rendón, 2003; Calónico and Ñopo, 2009). The present study attempts to examine these phenomena and contribute to the literature by examining the role of occupational segregation in explaining the gender wage gap in Mexico.4 An understanding of the factors driving male-female wage differentials is relevant since it helps direct public policies and evaluate if previous efforts to reduce gender wage inequalities have been rewarded.

The majority of studies that have examined gender wage differentials in Mexico have done so under the framework developed by Oaxaca (1973) and Blinder (1973), focusing on the issue of wage discrimination or unequal pay for equal work. Commonly referred to as the “index number” methodology, under Oaxaca-Blinder (OB) type decompositions, the discrimination effect is calculated as the unexplained difference between two reduced-form wage equations estimated separately for men and women. The estimation of these two wage equations is normally performed controlling for a standard set of productivity related variables, including variables denoting the individual’s occupational level, with the purpose of separating the effects of discrimination from those of legitimate compensating differentials (Reilly, 1991: 1). While including occupational controls allows interpreting the effect of the different occupational distributions of men and women, doing so is problematic since it assumes that occupations are exogenously given. Consequently, if occupational determination is subject to labour market discrimination, then this approach would be inappropriate (Liu et al., 2004).

Since the OB approach does not properly separate the effects of wage and job discrimination from those of occupational segregation, Brown, Moon and Zoloth (1980) suggest an alternative methodology that treats occupational choice as endogenously determined, and allows a decomposition of the wage gap into within and between occupational components.5 Under the Brown, Moon and Zoloth (BMZ) framework, the within and between components can be further decomposed into effects attributable to differences in observable characteristics and to differences in the estimated coefficients. In the context of between occupational effects, differences in the estimated coefficients provide an explicit estimation of the effect of occupational segregation on the gender wage gap. Identifying the relative importance of between against within occupational effects is important from a policy perspective, since the results may shed light on whether policies directed more at promoting equal pay within occupations should be prioritised, instead of measures that encourage a more equal access to different occupations (Liu et al., 2004).6

The present study contributes to the literature in several ways. First, an updated analysis based on the BMZ decomposition for the 2000-2010 period is performed. Furthermore, the Duncan and Duncan (1955) index of dissimilarity is also presented in order to provide an objective measure of the degree to which the occupational structures of males and females differ. Second, unlike previous studies that have emphasised the role of occupational segregation, we use census information which allows us to include rural localities and therefore study the entire Mexican labour market. Following Kidd and Shannon (1996) who raise awareness concerning the use of broadly defined occupational categories when performing wage decompositions, the much larger sample size of the census enables us to analyse the sensitivity of the results to the use of different levels of occupational aggregation. Third, in addition to the point estimates, we present standard errors for the different components of the Brown et al. (1980) decomposition. Finally, the sensitivity of the results is analysed where the estimated wage equations are corrected for self-selection into each occupation using the methodology outlined by Lee (1983).

Among the main results it is observed that gender wage differentials increased between 2000 and 2010. For both years, within occupation differentials positively contributed to the gender wage gap, whereas between occupation differentials provided a negative effect. Since within occupation differentials are driven by the unexplained component, the results suggest that the gender wage gap is primarily a product of differences in the average returns to productivity related characteristics within occupations. Furthermore, occupational segregation does not increase the gender wage gap since women do not appear to encounter barriers into high paying occupations. This result is robust to the use of different levels of occupational aggregation and when correcting the wage equations for selectivity-bias.

The study proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents a review of the related literature. Section 3 outlines the empirical and econometric methodologies. Section 4 describes the data and presents descriptive statistics. Section 5 discusses the main results. Section 6 tests the sensitivity of the results. Section 7 concludes.

Literature review

The literature that has examined gender wage differentials in Mexico is extensive. These studies usually report that women earn less than men, where the magnitude of the gender wage gap fluctuates depending on the period of study and the geographical coverage of the data source used.

Among the studies that have used the OB framework to examine gender wage differentials, Alarcón and McKinley (1994), based on data from the Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos de los Hogares (ENIGH, National Household Income and Expenditure Survey) from 1984, 1989 and 1992, observe that the gender wage gap increased from 23.3% in 1984, to 28.4% in 1989 and to 25.3% in 1992. In addition, for all three periods, the scholars find that at least 70.0% of the wage gap is attributed to discrimination, i.e. to differences in the economic returns to average characteristics.7 Based on data from the ENIGH from 2000, Martínez and Acevedo (2004) observe that approximately 85.0% of the gender wage gap is a product of differences in the economic returns to average characteristics. Alternatively, Mendoza and García (2009), using data from the Encuesta Nacional de Ocupación y Empleo (ENOE, National Occupation and Employment Survey) from 2006, observe that the majority of the gender wage gap, i.e. 87.6%, is a product of differences in average characteristics. Moreover, the authors report that this figure varies significantly by region, where gender wage discrimination is smallest in the north of Mexico and largest in the south.

Using an alternate methodology, Pagán and Ullibarri (2000), based on data from the Encuesta Nacional de Empleo Urbano (ENEU, National Urban Employment Survey) from 1995, analyse the role of group heterogeneity, i.e. differences by education level, age, firm size, sector of employment, and region of residence, on the gender earnings gap. The authors compute selectivity corrected earnings equations and estimate an additively decomposable index of the extent of gender unexplained wage inequality based on Jenkins (1994). The study shows that the unexplained wage gap is larger among workers with high education levels, which have full-time jobs, work in micro-firms, and are employed in the informal sector. On the other hand, Pagán and Sánchez (2000) use the Encuesta Regional de Servicios Financieros a Unidades de Protección Rural (SREFS, Survey of Rural Entrepreneurs and Financial Services) to study the factors that explain gender differences in workforce participation and in the incidence of self-employment in rural Mexico. Estimating a bivariate probit to analyse the propensity of individuals to enter the workforce and examine the incidence of self-employment among the employed, the authors show that if the female employment rate is predicted under the assumption that women face the male labour market structure, gender employment rate differentials almost disappear. While 88.2% of gender employment rate differences can be explained by structural demand and supply factors, only 11.8% is attributable to differences in individual endowments. Although the authors do not explicitly explore gender wage differentials, the results suggest that gender-related labour market discrimination is likely to be present in the wage or salaried sector.

Studies that emphasise the role of occupations when examining the gender wage gap in Mexico include Sánchez (1998), where the author employs the BMZ decomposition to evaluate the impact of between and within sectoral factors on male-female earnings differentials among rural and urban microenterprises. Based on data from the SREFS from 1994 and the Encuesta Nacional de Micronegocios (National Survey of Urban Microenterprises) from 1992, it is observed that female-headed microenterprises in rural and urban areas earn 64.0% and 50.0% less, respectively, than male-headed microenterprises. In addition, an estimated 35.0% of the earnings gap in urban areas can be attributed to differences in average characteristics, whereas in rural areas this figure rises to 42.0%. Only a small share of the gender earnings gap is explained by differences in sectoral distributions. In a descriptive analysis, Rendón (2003) examines gender differences in employment, segregation and wages. Based on various data sources including the 1990 and 2000 Population Censuses and the Encuesta Nacional de Empleo (ENE, National Employment Survey) from 2000, the author reports that male hourly wages surpass those of females by approximately 9.0%, where this gap varies significantly depending on the sector of employment. In addition, the scholar reports that women tend to be concentrated in specific occupations. When analysing the sector of employment of women, an increase in segregation by production sector between 1990 and 2010 is observed. Moreover, the study reports that there is high degree of vertical segregation in the Mexican labour market, where men tend to occupy higher ranking and better paying positions than women.8

Using data from the ENEU, Brown et al. (1999) examine the effect of occupational attainment on the increase in the gender wage gap between 1987 and 1993. The study uses the Wellington (1993) decomposition to disaggregate wage gap changes into relative changes in personal characteristics and changes in the returns to these characteristics. The authors also decompose gender differences in earnings between occupations and analyse the role of occupational attainment in the overall earnings gap by using the BMZ methodology. The results show that during the period of study there was an increase in the gender earnings gap attributed to relative changes in human capital endowments since, all else equal, wage coefficient changes would have slightly reduced the gender earnings gap. Moreover, while in 1987 the explained component accounted for 68.0% of the earnings gap, in 1993 it represented close to 73.0%. Furthermore, the gender earnings gap was mitigated by a substantial decline in gender differences in occupational attainment. The scholars also use the OB decomposition to study the effects of the occupational structure on the wage gap. It is observed that the majority of the earnings gap is a product of unexplained differences. When occupational controls are included, the authors find that occupational segregation reduces earnings differentials. In another study, Calónico and Ñopo (2009), based on data from the ENEU from 1994 to 2004, use a matching comparisons technique to examine the role of individual and family characteristics in determining gender segregation and wage gaps. The scholars report that the elimination of vertical segregation would decrease the gender wage gap by 5.0 percentage points. On the other hand, the elimination of occupational segregation would increase gender wage differentials by 6.0 percentage points. Furthermore, it is observed that, during the period of study, the role of occupational segregation in determining the gender wage gap increased, whereas the relative importance of vertical segregation decreased.

Recent studies have focused on studying the gender wage gap at different parts of the wage distribution. Among these, using primarily census data from 1990 to 2010, employing the methodology put forward by DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux (1996) and correcting the analysis for selection of women into the labour market, Campos-Vázquez and Arceo-Gómez (2014) observe a consistent pattern of “sticky floors” and a decreasing pattern of “glass ceilings” over the period of study. In addition, the authors report that the majority of the gender wage gap is a result of differences in prices. Moreover, the scholars show that the gender wage gap becomes larger when correcting for selection, which suggests that women are positively selected into the labour market. Finally, Popli (2013) also examines gender wage differentials throughout the entire distribution in both the formal and informal sectors based on data from the ENIGH from 1996 and 2006. Taking into account the probability of employment into the wage or salaried sector, the study finds that the gender wage gap differs considerably by sector of employment. Contrary to raw gender wage differentials, the selection-adjusted gender wage gap is higher in the formal sector compared to the informal sector. Using different techniques including the OB decomposition, the measure proposed by Jenkins (1994) and non-parametric techniques, the scholar shows that the unexplained gender wage gap varies according to the sector of employment, where the unexplained term is higher in the formal sector relative to the informal sector. The study also reports that in both sectors the unexplained gender wage gap decreased during the period of analysis, where there is evidence of a “glass ceiling” in the formal sector, with the unexplained male-female wage gap being higher in the upper tail of the distribution.

Methodology

The decomposition developed by Brown et al. (1980), i.e. the BMZ decomposition, requires the estimation of occupation-specific wage regressions for male (m) and female (f) workers:

wikm=Xikmβ^km+εikm (1)

wikf=Xikfβ^kf+εikf (2)

where w ik represents the natural logarithm of hourly wages for individual i employed in occupation k=1,2,K; β^k ; is a vector of wage coefficients specific to occupation k, and ε ik is the error term. Moreover, let w¯m and w¯f denote mean male and female wages, and Pkm and Pkf represent the proportion of male and female workers employed in occupation k. Thus, the overall mean gender wage differential can be calculated from Eqs. (1) and (2) in the following manner:

w¯m-w¯f=k=1k(Pkmw¯km- Pkfw¯kf) (3)

w¯m-w¯f=k=1kPkfX¯mk-X¯kfβ^km+k=1kX¯kmβ^km(Pkm-P^kf)+k=1kPkfX¯kf(β^km-β^kf)+k=1kX¯kmβ^km(P^kf-Pkm) (4)

where adding and subtracting terms on the right hand side of Eq. (3) and manipulating terms yields Eq. (4). In the decomposition, X¯ is a vector of mean values of the exogenous variables,P^kf and denotes the proportion of female workers who would be employed in occupation k if they were to face the same occupational structure as that encountered by male workers. The first component on the right hand side of Eq. (4) captures wage differentials derived from differences in average characteristics within occupations, while the second component explains differentials generated by dissimilarities in participation shares between occupations. These two terms constitute the within explained (WE) and between explained (BE) components, respectively. The third term reflects compensating differentials within occupations, while occupational segregation and different preferences between the two groups are captured by the fourth term. These two terms constitute the within unexplained (WU) and between unexplained (BU) components, respectively. The WU component can be understood as the wage effect of vertical or hierarchical segregation, since it captures unexplained differences in the structure of occupational achievement or the unobserved factors that determine why certain groups are under- or overrepresented in higher paying positions within individual occupations (Salardi, 2012). On the other hand, the BU term may be interpreted as the wage effect of horizontal or occupational segregation, since it provides an indication for the equality of access between men and women to various occupations (Liu et al., 2004).

In addition to the occupation specific wage regressions, the BMZ decomposition requires a method for predicting P^kf. Due to data constraints, the latter is done through an estimation of a reduced form multinomial logit (MNL) model. The MNL captures how different variables affect the probability of an individual working in a given occupation, while treating the occupational choice as endogenously determined. This probability may be defined as:

Pik=Pryi=Occk=exp(Ziγ^k)1+k=1k-1exp(Ziγ^k)+ηik (5)

where Zi is a vector of labour supply and demand related exogenous variables presumed to determine occupational attainment; γ^k is a vector of coefficients corresponding to occupation k, and ηik is the error term. The reduced form MNL captures both supply driven differences in group preferences and demand driven constraints. Both of these factors are likely to generate differences in the estimated coefficients between men and women, where the limited access to some occupations for female workers suggests the presence of occupational segregation (Démurger et al., 2009: 613).9

To obtain P^kf, the estimates of the parameters of Eq. (5) are calculated for males and the data for females is subsequently substituted into the estimated equations. This produces for every female observation a vector of predicted probabilities of belonging to each occupation. Then, these probabilities are added over observations to produce the predicted or non-discriminatory occupational distribution of each female worker.

Data description

The data used in this study comes from a 10.6% and 10.0% random sample of Mexico’s 2000 and 2010 Census of Population and Housing, respectively. The information is collected by the Instituto Nacional de Geografía y Estadística (INEGI, National Institute of Geography and Statistics) and provided by IPUMS-International (2013). The sample includes full-time salaried workers between the ages of 18 and 65 years that report non-zero wages.10 Furthermore, workers located at the bottom and top 0.5% of the wage distribution are omitted in order to eliminate the effects generated by the presence of outliers. All figures are in real June 2010 Mexican pesos (MXP).

Given its substantial sample size, the use of census data provides a clear advantage over Mexico’s traditional labour force surveys, i.e. the ENEU, ENE and ENOE. The census allows having a larger number of observations for each individual occupation and allows using a more disaggregated occupational classification scheme. The use of smaller samples has its drawbacks as it may lead to the use of more broadly defined occupational categories, which in turn may hide wage differences and heterogeneity within generally defined occupations.

Descriptive statistics

Table 1 presents descriptive statistics, where significant differences between male and female characteristics are observed. Among these, for both 2000 and 2010 mean log hourly wages of men are larger than those of women. Specifically, this figure is .021 log points higher in 2000 and .026 log points higher in 2010.11 A similar relationship is observed regarding the age structure, where in both periods men are slightly older than women. Given that age is positively correlated with labour market experience, this suggests that one of the reasons why male wages are higher is because on average they have more experience than their female counterparts. With respect to human capital levels, on average female workers have higher education levels than males. This difference slightly increased during the period of study, going from 1.34 years in 2000 to 1.36 years in 2010. The fact that women have higher levels of education but lower hourly wages than men implies that their returns to education may be smaller. On the other hand, men have substantially longer work-weeks than women and have a lower likelihood of engaging in part-time work. The difference in the size of the work-week is one of the main factors behind the observed gender wage gap when focusing on weekly wages. Moreover, for both 2000 and 2010, women have higher participation rates in the formal sector than men, which tends to be associated with higher productivity levels and therefore higher wages. In addition, male salaried workers have a higher probability of being married than their female counterparts. Since labour force participation rates differ substantial between male and female workers, this may be signalling that women are likely to drop out of the labour force once they engage in marriage. In summary, taking the above differences into consideration, it cannot be ruled out that the gender wage gap may be driven by socioeconomic and demographic characteristics instead of other factors such as occupational segregation.12

Table 1 Descriptive statistics, means and standard errors 

Variable 2000 2010
Men Women Men Women
Log hourly wages 2.933 2.912 3.159 3.133
(0.706) (0.711) (0.639) (0.665)
Age 33.97 32.31 35.83 35.40
(11.14) (10.13) (11.49) (10.74)
Schooling 8.500 9.839 9.677 11.04
(4.407) (4.253) (4.337) (4.229)
Hours worked per week 45.35 43.35 45.48 43.59
(6.085) (6.514) (6.115) (6.497)
Formal 57.98 68.19 55.80 66.10
Married 72.50 43.51 71.59 48.18
Rural 17.44 8.118 17.18 8.705
Part-time employment 5.944 14.73 7.438 15.59
Labour force participation 88.73 36.95 90.85 43.00
Unemployment rate 1.479 0.894 5.591 2.734
Observations 780.987 362,879 794,462 379,410

Source: Authors elaboration based on the 2000 and 2010 Mexican Census. Data includes individuals between 18 and 65 years of age. Hourly wages are in natural logarithms and in real June 2010 MXP. Standard errors are in parentheses.

Turning our attention to mean log hourly wages within occupations, some interesting results emerge. As seen in Table 2, for both periods within all occupational categories men have higher wages than women. In the year 2000, the gender wage gap was the largest at the “Crafts and related trades workers” category, rising to .303 log points, and it was the smallest at the “Technicians and associate professionals” category, standing at .048 log points. At the highest paying occupation, i.e. the “Legislators, senior officials and managers” category, the male-female wage differential was also substantial, where it was equal to .210 log points. In 2010, the gender wage gap was the largest at the “Plant and machine operators and assemblers” category, rising to .277 log points, and it was the smallest at the “Skilled agricultural and fishery workers” category, standing at .004 log points. Finally, in 2010 at the top of the occupational distribution the male-female wage gap decreased to .083 log points.

Table 2 Log hourly wages by occupation, means and standard errors 

Occupation 2000 2010
Men Women Men Women
Legislators, senior officials and managers 4.107 3.897 3.895 3.812
(0.730) (0.698) (0.655) (0.648)
Professionals 3.869 3.683 3.931 3.849
(0.626) (0.595) (0.629) (0.617)
Technicians and associate professionals 3.317 3.269 3.578 3.533
(0.600) (0.601) (0.596) (0.595)
Clerks 3.245 3.121 3.255 3.214
(0.650) (0.590) (0.550) (0.523)
Crafts and related trades workers 2.925 2.622 3.186 3.086
(0.573) (0.537) (0.533) (0.718)
Service workers and shop and market sales 2.902 2.642 3.071 2.874
(0.631) (0.628) (0.590) (0.561)
Plant and machine operators and assemblers 2.893 2.669 3.091 2.814
(0.488) (0.360) (0.513) (0.389)
Elementary occupations 2.647 2.425 2.833 2.751
(0.491) (0.519) (0.463) (0.464)
Skilled agricultural and fishery workers 2.271 2.139 2.613 2.609
(0.539) (0.557) (0.493) (0.484)
Observations 780,987 362,879 794,462 379,410

Source: Authors elaboration based on the 2000 and 2010 Mexican Census. Data includes individuals between 18 and 65 years of age that work 30 or more hours per week. Hourly wages are in natural logarithms and in real June 2010 MXP. Standard errors are in parentheses.

Results

The first-stage of the Brown et al. (1980) decomposition requires the estimation of K occupation specific wage regressions for male and female workers as defined in Eqs. (1) and (2), and a MNL occupational attainment model as defined in Eq. (5). While we do not present the first-stage estimations due to space constraints, we briefly discuss the main findings. Furthermore, these results are available upon request.

The estimation of nine occupation specific wage regressions show that there are significant differences in the returns to education between men and women. In 2000, in the “Legislators, senior officials and managers” category, males had higher returns to education than females. In the rest of the distribution, the returns to education of males and females were similar with the exception of the “Plant and machine operators and assemblers” category, where the returns for males were substantially larger. By 2010, female returns to education surpassed those of males in the top paying category and were similar among all workers in the rest of the occupational distribution. Based on the previous outcomes, it can be inferred that gender differences in returns to schooling are in large part driven by dissimilarities in the occupational structures. Regarding the returns to potential experience, in both 2000 and 2010, women were better compensated than men for low experience levels in the highest paying occupations. On the other hand, in the lower part of the occupational distribution, the returns to experience were larger for men. Additional results are as expected, where being in formal employment, married and working in an urban locality are positively related with higher hourly wages. Moreover, the state unemployment rate is negatively correlated with hourly wages, particularly in the highest paying categories. In summary, the results show that there is substantial variation in the effects of the covariates on male and female wages depending on the occupation of employment.

Attention now turns to the MNL occupational attainment model, where the “Elementary occupations” category was used as the reference group. Among the explanatory variables, education plays an important role in predicting employment into the two highest paying occupations, i.e. the “Legislators, senior officials and managers” and “Professionals” categories. The effect of education is strongest among women and is significant in both 2000 and 2010. A different story emerges in low skilled categories, where an additional year of schooling has either a much smaller effect or reduces the probability of attachment. Regarding potential experience, in 2000 this was generally associated with an increase in the probability of attachment at the top of the distribution. Moreover, its effect was larger among males and negative for females in low-paying categories. While a similar relationship is observed among males in 2010, for females experience it was positively associated with attachment in the highest-paying occupation and negatively associated with attachment in other occupations. On the other hand, variables related to the worker’s family situation show that, in 2000, the married population had a higher probability of being employed outside of the “Elementary occupations” category, where the size of this coefficient was fairly stable across occupations. In 2010, whereas a comparable relationship was observed among women, no clear pattern emerged among males. Pertaining to the number of children under age six, in the year 2000 this had a negative effect on the probability of working in the “Legislators, senior officials and managers” category for all workers, although the coefficients are not statistically significant. A different relationship is observed in 2010, where the coefficient was positive for both genders at the top of the occupational distribution, although it was only significant for women. Regarding family size, for both periods and genders, the variable had a negative effect on the probability of attachment in the highest paying occupations. Altogether, the effect of the explanatory variables on occupational attainment varies according to the gender and between periods. This suggests that men and women are allocated differently between occupations based on their observed characteristics.

Brown-Moon-Zoloth decomposition

The results of the BMZ decomposition of log wage differentials between men and women disaggregated by year and locality size are presented in Table 3. In 2000, the hourly log wage differential between men and women stood at .021 log points. The sum of the WE and BE components, which equalled -.043 log points, suggests that according to their average characteristics women actually should have had higher hourly wages than men. Nonetheless, analysing these two terms separately shows substantial heterogeneity in their effects. Specifically, the WE component, which rose to .023 log points, was roughly equal to the total gender wage gap. This implies that the entirety of the gender wage gap was accounted for by differences in average characteristics. On the other hand, the BE component stood at -.066 log points indicating that, on average, women were allocated in better remunerated positions than men. With respect to the unexplained components which capture differences in coefficients, the sum of the WU and BU terms was equal to .064 log points or 304.7% of the gender wage gap. This signals that based on the returns to their average characteristics, the size of the gender wage gap should have been larger than what is in fact observed. Nonetheless, when separating the two unexplained components significantly different patterns emerge. The WU term, equivalent to .167 log points, suggests that wage differentials are largely driven by vertical segregation, i.e. by differences in the returns to average characteristics within each occupation. On the other hand, the BU component which captures the effect of occupational segregation negatively contributes to the gender wage gap. Somewhat surprisingly, this implies that women encountered fewer barriers to entry into high paying occupations than men.

Table 3 BMZ decomposition of log hourly wage differentials between men and women 

2000 2010
Total Urban Rural Total Urban Rural
Total log hourly wage differential .021 .081 .017 .026 .066 .007
(.001) (.001) (.002) (.001) (.001) (.002)
Explained: Differences in mean characteristics
Within .023 .026 .009 -.018 -.017 -.007
(.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001)
Between -.066 -.046 -.103 -.030 -.025 -.075
(.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001)
Unexplained: Differences in coefficients
Within .167 .165 .209 .132 .134 .152
(.001) (.001) (.002) (.001) (.001) (.002)
Between -.103 -.064 -.098 -.058 -.026 -.063
(.001) (.001) (.002) (.001) (.001) (.002)

Note: Male OLS coefficients are taken as the non-discriminatory vector.

Source: Authors elaboration based on the 2000 and 2010 Mexican Census. Standard errors are in parentheses. Decomposition based on OLS regressions which include as independent variables years of education, potential experience, potential experience squared, the state unemployment rate, and dummy variables for marital status, formal-informal work and region of residence.

With respect to differences between urban and rural localities, the gender wage gap varies significantly when making this distinction, rising to .081 and .017 log points in urban and rural settings, respectively. In addition, in urban localities the sum of the WE and BE components equalled -.020 log points. On the other hand, in rural areas the WU and BU components totalled .101 log points.

In 2010, the gender wage gap stood at .026 log points. With the exception of the WE term which equalled -.018 log points, the sign and overall interpretation of the different components of the BMZ decomposition are generally similar to those observed in 2000. The negative sign of the WE component suggests that according to their average characteristics within occupations, female hourly wages should have been higher than those of males. Moreover, the BE component which stood at -.030 log points denotes that, on average, women were allocated in better remunerated positions than men. Relative to 2000, the reduction in absolute value of the BE term signals that, while in 2010 women still occupied better compensated positions than men, male-female occupational structures became more alike during this period. Concerning the unexplained components, the sum of the WU and BU terms totalled .074 log points or 284.6% of the wage gap. While the WU component stood at .132 log points, its reduction with respect to 2000 implies that the differences in the returns to average characteristics between men and women decreased by 21.0% during the period of study. The decline in the WU term between 2000 and 2010 signals a positive change towards a more equal wage compensation within occupations among men and women. On the other hand, the contribution of occupational segregation to the wage gap captured through the BU component was again negative, although smaller in absolute value relative to 2000. This suggests that in 2010, women still encountered fewer barriers to entry into high paying occupations than men. Moreover, the statistically significant effect of the BU term in 2000 and 2010 implies that, in both periods, workers were assigned to different occupations based on non-productivity related characteristics.

Finally, gender wage differentials once again differ when making the distinction according to the size of the locality of residence. Specifically, the wage gap stood at .066 and .007 log points in urban and rural localities, respectively. In urban areas, the sum of the WE and BE terms equalled -.042 log points, while in rural localities the sum of the WU and BU components totalled .089 log points.

Differences in the occupational structure

The observed and predicted occupational distributions of men and women across the nine occupational categories for 2000 and 2010 are presented in Table 4, where the allocation rule of males, derived from Eq. (5), is used to obtain the female simulated occupational structure. This scenario can be interpreted as men and women having similar preferences and the labour market providing equal opportunity and occupational access to both groups. Furthermore, the Duncan and Duncan (1955) index of dissimilarity is used in order to provide a better understanding of the degree of gender differences in the occupational structures. The index is given by:

Source: Authors elaboration based on the 2000 and 2010 Mexican Census. Predicted distribution by occupation represents the proportion of female workers who would be in each occupation if they were to follow the same occupational sorting function as men, based on the estimation of a MNL model of occupational attainment for male workers.

Table 4 Distribution by occupation and dissimilarity indices 

D=(12)k=1K|Pkf-Pkm| (6)

where Eq. (6) is interpreted as measuring the proportion of male workers required to change occupations in order to obtain the same occupational distribution generated by female workers. An index value equal to zero reflects that there is no occupational dissimilarity between both groups. On the other hand, an index value equal to one indicates that men and women are never in the same occupations.

With respect to the observed occupational distribution, in 2000, at the extremes of the distribution, men had higher participation rates in both the highest paying occupation, i.e. in the “Legislators, senior officials and managers” category, and in the lowest paying one, i.e. in the “Skilled agricultural and fishery workers” category. Nonetheless, at the middle of the occupational distribution, a different picture emerges. In general, women had higher participation rates than men at the top-half of the distribution, whereas at the bottom-half no clear pattern is observed. Focusing on the Duncan index of dissimilarity, it shows that, in 2000, approximately 32.1% of women would have needed to change occupations in order to obtain the same occupational distribution as men. On the other hand, in 2010, women had higher participation rates than men in the four highest paying occupations. Furthermore, while the share of female workers employed in the “Elementary occupations” category remained relatively stable between 2000 and 2010, a much larger proportion of men were employed in this category at the end of this period. As a result, the Duncan index slightly decreased to .305 in 2010.

Comparing observed distributions to predicted ones, according to the male allocation rule, female workers were under-represented at the “Legislators, senior officials and managers” category in 2000, but not in 2010. In both 2000 and 2010, women were under-represented at the bottom of the occupational distribution. This result can be inferred since under the male occupational sorting function female workers had a much larger participation rate in the “Skilled agricultural and fishery workers” category compared to their actual share. On the other hand, in both years, women were over-represented in the “Elementary occupations” category, which is one of the lowest paying occupations and employs a much larger share of male and female workers.

When women follow the same allocation rule as men, the Duncan index is reduced significantly to 7.7% in 2000 and 5.0% in 2010. Jointly, the previous findings imply that only a small part of the differences in the occupational structures between men and women are driven by different sorting functions. These dissimilarities are likely a product of differences in productivity related characteristics and cultural factors which assign different roles in the labour market for men and women.

Sensitivity checks

Different levels of occupational aggregation

Because of computational problems and the presence of small cell sizes within certain occupations, the majority of studies that employ the BMZ decomposition use a very aggregated level of occupational classification.13 Nevertheless, the use of broadly defined categories conceals the importance of occupations when performing wage decompositions, since it likely conceals significant wage differences and heterogeneity within the generally defined occupations. To examine the sensitivity of our results to the number of categories, the analysis is performed under different levels of occupational aggregation.

The results of the BMZ decomposition at the one-digit and two-digit occupational aggregation levels are presented in Table 5.14 For 2000, augmenting the number of categories did not increase the proportion of the wage gap attributed to the explained component, i.e. the sum of the WE and BE terms. On the contrary, it decreased from -.043 log points at the one-digit level to -.052 at the two-digit level. Moreover, the WE, BE and WU components were marginally reduced, while the BU term was subject to an increase. For 2010, expanding the number of categories led to a slight increase in the proportion of the wage gap attributed to the explained component, where the sum of the WE and BE terms rose from -.048 log points at the one-digit level to -.036 log points at the two-digit level. Moreover, while the WE component grew by .019 log points, the BE term was reduced by .007 log points.

Table 5 Sensitivity of BMZ decomposition of log hourly wage differentials between men and women to different levels of occupational aggregation 

Number of occupations 2000 2010
WE BE WU BU WE BE WU BU
One-digit .023 - .066 .167 -.103 -.018 -.030 .132 -.058
(.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001)
Two-digit .016 -.068 .150 -.078 .001 -.037 .123 -.062
(.001) (.001) (.002) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.002) (.001)

Note: One-digit denotes nine occupational categories for 2000 and 2010. Two-digit denotes 18 occupational categories for 2000 and 49 categories for 2010.

Source: Authors elaboration based on the 2000 and 2010 Mexican Census. Standard errors are in parentheses.

In general, the main results for the year 2000 are not very sensitive to the number of categories, since augmenting the number of occupations does not increase the proportion of the gender wage gap attributed to the explained component. On the other hand, for 2010 the WE term varies considerably between the one and two-digit levels, suggesting that this component is sensitive to the number of occupational categories. Nonetheless, the fact that the BU term is always negative and remains relatively stable provides further evidence that occupational segregation does not increase the gender wage gap in Mexico.

Controlling for self-selection

Since occupational attainment is determined by the interaction between demand and supply factors where individuals may differ among unobservable characteristics between occupations, the sample of workers observed in each occupation may not be random. In this section, we use the information obtained from Eq. (5) to adjust the occupation specific wage equations for potential effects generated by selection bias. Following Lee (1983), the wage equations are modified accordingly and conditional on occupation k being chosen are given by:

Wik=Xikβ^k+θ^kλik+ξik (7)

where θ^k=σkρk,λik=-ϕ[τ(Zikγ^k)]F(Ziγ^k), and ξik is the error term.

In Eq. (7),Φ is the standard normal probability density function, σ k is the standard error of the disturbance term, and ρ k is the correlation between the error terms of Eqs. (5) and (7). The function is a strictly increasing transformation that converts the random variables associated with occupational attainment into a standard normal variant, i.e. τ=Φ -1- (F), where Φ is the standard normal cumulative distribution function, and F is the distribution function of the MNL as defined in Eq. (5).

The procedure is carried out in two stages. First, estimates of the coefficient vector in the MNL equation are obtained from Eq. (5). Second, these estimated coefficients are used to calculate λ ik . The variables included in the vector Z ik are expected to affect the worker’s desire for a particular occupation as well as the willingness of employers to hire the individual. The analysis uses as excluded instruments that identify selectivity indicators for the number of children below six and household size. It is assumed that these demographic variables shift the probability of being employed in occupation k but do not affect wages. Nonetheless, attaining identification in the selectivity model is challenging given that no available variable can be considered a completely exogenous instrument.

The results of the BMZ methodology controlling for self-selection into occupations are presented in Table 6.15 In these estimations, the correction term is not considered as constituting part of the explained or unexplained components and instead is examined separately. Moreover, the four previously defined terms of the decomposition are grouped and demarcated as representing the wage offer gap or unconditional wage differential. This is equivalent to setting the selectivity effects to zero in each equation, where the wage offer gap is taken to indicate the wage a worker randomly drawn from the population would receive if she or he were selected into the occupational category in question (Gyourko and Tracy, 1988).

Table 6 BMZ decomposition of log hourly wage differentials between men and women with Lee (1983) correction 

2000 2010
Total Urban Rural Total Urban Rural
Total log wage differential .021 .082 .017 .026 .066 .007
(.002) (.003) (.005) (.003) (.003) (.008)
Explained: Differences in mean characteristics
Within .012 .013 .002 -.022 -.020 -.007
(.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001)
Between -.085 -.081 -.112 -.057 -.039 -.093
(.001) (.001) (.002) (.001) (.001) (.003)
Unexplained: Differences in coefficients
Within .002 -.096 .067 -.075 -.150 .015
(.003) (.004) (.011) (.005) (.005) (.012)
Between -.130 -.132 -.075 -.085 -.085 -.089
(.001) (.001) (.004) (.002) (.002) (.006)
Wage offer gap -.203 -.296 -.118 -.241 -.295 -.173
(.004) (.004) (.012) (.005) (.006) (.014)
Selection term differential .222 .378 .135 .265 .360 .181
(.001) (.002) (.002) (.002) (.002) (.003)

Note: Male OLS coefficients are taken as the non-discriminatory vector.

Source: Authors elaboration based on the 2000 and 2010 Mexican Census. Standard errors are in parentheses. Decomposition based on OLS regressions which include as independent variables years of education, potential experience, potential experience squared, the state unemployment rate, a selection term, and dummy variables for marital status, formal-informal work and region of residence.

Among the results, it can be seen that the selection term differential is always positive, implying that the wage offer gap is smaller than the total wage gap, and that gender wage differentials are smaller and negative after correcting for self-selection. Moreover, for the full sample in both 2000 and 2010, the BE term now stands at -.085 and -.057 log points, respectively. This reinforces the result obtained in Section 4 which indicates that, on average, women are allocated in better remunerated positions than men. A similar finding is observed when dividing the sample between urban and rural workers. On the other hand, when controlling for self-selection the WU term is no longer the main driver of the gender wage gap, since this component is now considerably smaller for both years and across different samples. Instead, the gender wage gap is mostly a product of differences in the selection term. Furthermore, there are considerable differences in the magnitude of the WU across time, where this component stood at .002 and -.075 log points in 2000 and 2010, respectively. These results suggest that when controlling for self-selection, women do not appear to encounter vertical or hierarchical segregation in the labour market. Regarding the BU component, it is once again observed for the full sample in 2000 and 2010 that this term negatively contributed to the total wage gap. This implies that women encountered fewer barriers to entry into high paying occupations than men, where the effect of the BU term is now bigger in absolute value. Additionally, the WE term went from positively contributing to the gender wage gap in 2000 to having a negative effect in 2010. Moreover, the BE component increased from -.085 to -.057 log points, whereas the BU term increased from -.130 to -.085 log points.16

Conclusions

This study examined the role of occupational segregation in explaining the gender wage gap in Mexico. Based on the BMZ decomposition, the results show that male-female hourly wage differentials increased between 2000 and 2010. For both years, the sum of the within occupation wage differentials components positively contributed to the total gender wage gap, whereas the sum of the between occupation wage differentials components had the opposite effect. The gender wage gap is mostly a product of compensating differences within rather than across occupational categories. Furthermore, since within occupation wage differentials are largely driven by the unexplained component, the findings suggest that the gender wage gap is primarily a product of differences in the average returns to productivity related characteristics within occupations. While the study shows that the occupational structure of male workers differs considerably from that of their female counterparts, occupational segregation does not increase the gender wage gap, since women do not appear to encounter barriers into high paying occupations. The effect of the role of occupational segregation is robust to the use of different levels of occupational aggregation and remains relatively stable when correcting the occupation-specific wage equations for selectivity-bias using the methodology outlined by Lee (1983).

While occupational segregation does not play an important role in the wage disadvantage experienced by women, it is likely that the gender wage gap is mostly driven by partial segregation within the defined occupational categories given the large values of the within unexplained component. Consequently, the implementation of policies intended at balancing gender representation across occupations can have only a limited effect and are likely to be less effective than policies designed at undoing partially segregated positions within given occupations. Future legislation should be directed at encouraging equal pay within occupations rather than at endorsing a more equal distribution of men and women across occupations. Moreover, the fact that senior positions tend to be occupied by males while the subordinates are commonly female is likely to represent an ineffective allocation of human resources which generates inefficiencies in the labour market.

References

Aguayo-Téllez, E., Airola, J., Juhn, C. & Villegas-Sánchez, C. (2013). Did trade liberalization help women? The case of Mexico in the 1990s, in Polachek S. and Tatsiramos K. (eds.), New analyses of worker well-being (Research in Labor Economics, Volume 38). Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing Limited, 1-35. [ Links ]

Alarcón, D. & McKinley, T. (1994). Gender differences in wages and human capital: Case study of female and male urban workers in Mexico from 1984 to 1992. Frontera Norte, 6(12): 41-50. [ Links ]

Blinder, A. (1973). Wage discrimination: Reduced form and structural estimates. Journal of Human Resources, 8(4): 436-455. [ Links ]

Brown, R., Moon, M. & Zoloth, B. (1980). Incorporating occupational attainment in studies of male-female earnings differentials. Journal of Human Resources , 15(1): 3-28. [ Links ]

Brown, C., Pagán, J. & Rodríguez-Oreggia, E. (1999). Occupational attainment and gender earnings differentials in Mexico. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 53(1): 123-135. [ Links ]

Calónico, S. & Ñopo, H. (2009). Gender segregation in the workplace and wage gaps: Evidence from urban Mexico, in Bishop, J. (ed.), Occupational and residential segregation (Research on Economic Inequality, vol. 17). Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing Limited , 245-270. [ Links ]

Campos-Vázquez, R. y Arceo-Gómez, E. (2014). Evolución de la brecha salarial de género en México. El Trimestre Económico, 81(3): 619-653. [ Links ]

Démurger, S., Gurgand, M., Shi, L., & Ximing, Y. (2009). Migrants as second-class workers in urban China? A decomposition analysis. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(4): 610-628. [ Links ]

DiNardo, J., Fortin, N. & Lemieux, T. (1996). Labor market institutions and the distribution of wages, 1973-1992: A semiparametric approach. Econometrica, 64(5): 1001-1044. [ Links ]

Dolton, P. & Kidd, M. (1994). Occupational access and wage discrimination. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 56(4):457-474. [ Links ]

Duncan, O. & Duncan, B. (1955). A methodological analysis of segregation indexes. American Sociological Review, 20(2): 210-217. [ Links ]

Duval, R. y Orraca, P. (2011). Análisis por cohortes de la participación laboral en México (1987-2009). El Trimestre Económico , 78(2): 343-375. [ Links ]

Ehrenberg, R. & Smith, R. (2012). Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy. New York: Pearson Education. [ Links ]

Firpo, S., Fortin, N. & Lemieux, T. (2009). Unconditional quantile regressions. Econometrica , 77(3): 953-973. [ Links ]

Gyourko, J. & Tracy, J. (1988). An analysis of public- and private-sector wages allowing for endogenous choices of both government and union status. Journal of Labor Economics, 6(2): 229-253. [ Links ]

Integrated Public Use Microdata Series International (IPUMS-International). (2013). Version 6.2, Minnesota Population Center, Minneapolis, University of Minnesota. [ Links ]

Jenkins, S. (1994). Earnings discrimination measurement: A distributional approach. Journal of Econometrics, 61(1): 81-102. [ Links ]

Kidd, M. (1993). Sex discrimination and occupational segregation in the Australian labour market. Economic Record, 69(204): 44-55. [ Links ]

Kidd, M. & Shannon, M. (1994). An update and expansion of the Canadian evidence on gender wage differentials. Canadian Journal of Economics, 27(4): 918-938. [ Links ]

Kidd, M. & Shannon, M. (1996). Does the level of occupational aggregation affect estimates of the gender wage gap? Industrial and Labor Relations Review , 49(2): 317-329. [ Links ]

Lee, L.-F. (1983). Generalized econometric models with selectivity. Econometrica , 51(2): 507-512. [ Links ]

Liu, P.-W., Zhang, J. & Chong, S.-C. (2004). Occupational segregation and wage differentials between natives and immigrants: Evidence from Hong Kong. Journal of Development Economics, 73(1): 395-413. [ Links ]

Machado, J. & Mata, J. (2005). Counterfactual decomposition of changes in wage distributions using quantile regression. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 20(4): 445-465. [ Links ]

Martínez, I. y Acevedo, G. (2004). La brecha salarial en México con enfoque de género: Capital humano, discriminación y selección muestral. Ciencia UANL, 7(1): 66-71. [ Links ]

Mendoza. J. y García, K. (2009). Discriminación salarial por género en México. Problemas del Desarrollo, 40(156): 77-99. [ Links ]

Miller, P. (1987). The wage effect of the occupational segregation of women in Britain. Economic Journal, 97(388): 885-896. [ Links ]

Ñopo, H. (2008). Matching as a tool to decompose wage gaps. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(2): 290-299. [ Links ]

Oaxaca, R. (1973). Male-female wage differentials in urban labor markets. International Economic Review, 14(3): 693-709. [ Links ]

Pagán, J. & Sánchez, S. (2000). Gender differences in labor market decisions: Evidence from rural Mexico. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 48(3): 619-637. [ Links ]

Pagán, J. & Ullibarri, M. (2000). Group heterogeneity and the gender earnings gap in Mexico. Economía Mexicana, 9(1): 23-40. [ Links ]

Popli, G. (2013). Gender wage discrimination in Mexico: A distributional approach. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series A, 176(2): 295-319. [ Links ]

Reilly, B. (1991). Occupational segregation and selectivity bias in occupational wage equations: An empirical analysis using Irish data. Applied Economics, 23(1): 1-8. [ Links ]

Rendón, T. (2003). Empleo, segregación y salarios por género, in de la Garza E. and Salas C. (coords.), La situación del trabajo en México. Mexico City: Universidad Autónoma Metropolitana, 129-150. [ Links ]

Salardi, P. (2012). An analysis of pay and occupational differences by gender and race in Brazil-1987 to 2006. PhD thesis, University of Sussex. [ Links ]

Sánchez, S. (1998). Gender earnings differentials in the microenterprise sector: Evidence from rural and urban Mexico. World Bank Working Paper No. 36149. World Bank, Washington, D.C. [ Links ]

Wellington, A. (1993). Changes in the male/female wage gap: 1976-85. Journal of Human Resources , 28(2): 383-409. [ Links ]

4Following the related literature (e.g. Liu, Zhang and Chong, 2004), occupational segregation is said to exist if workers are assigned to different occupations based on non-productivity related characteristics. This is not to be confused with occupational structure, which refers to the distribution of workers between occupations. Differences in the occupational structures of men and women do not necessarily suggest that there is discrimination in the labour market. Nonetheless, if women face barriers to entry into occupations or if their occupational choices are limited by lower returns to their productivity related characteristics within occupations, then different occupational structures do indeed reflect discrimination (Ehrenberg and Smith, 2012).

5In recent years, a variety of decomposition techniques that focus on analysing wage differentials beyond the mean have been developed (e.g. Machado and Mata, 2005; Firpo, Fortin and Lemieux, 2009). Nevertheless, unlike the Brown et al. (1980) methodology, these decompositions are unable to properly identify the effects of occupations on wages since they treat occupations as being exogenously determined. Since the present study examines the role of occupational segregation in the gender wage gap, the Brown et al. (1980) decomposition represents our preferred methodology. Concerning the alternate method developed by Ñopo (2008), it has been recently applied to the Mexican case by Calónico and Ñopo (2009).

6The international literature that has analysed gender wage differentials using the BMZ methodology includes the original work of Brown et al. (1980) for the U.S., Miller (1987) and Dolton and Kidd (1994) for the U.K., Reilly (1991) for Ireland, Kidd and Shannon (1994, 1996) for Canada, and Salardi (2012) for Brazil, among others. These studies have generally concluded that most of the gender wage gap is a product of within occupation effects, where occupational segregation tends to play only a minor role.

7A common inconvenience with OB type decompositions is that all of the variables that affect wages are rarely available, in which case the extent of labour market discrimination will tend to be overstated.

8The event when men and women are clustered in different occupations is commonly referred to as horizontal or occupational segregation, and is normally reflected in wage disadvantages between occupations. The event when gender differences are present within a single occupation where workers occupy different categories is commonly known as vertical or hierarchical segregation, and is normally reflected in wage disadvantages within occupations.

9Potential demand factors driving the BU component can be for example employers’ affinity to work with people from the same or the opposite gender, a preference for either male or female workers based on perceived gender differences in the ability to lead or follow or relate to other workers, or the belief that certain occupations should be occupied by men and other by women, among others.

10Full-time employment is defined as working 30 or more hours per week.

11These figures can be easily converted to percentage terms. Let x represent the difference in mean log hourly wages between men and women, the percentage wage differential is then e x - 1.

12Since the sample used in the study only includes full-time salaried workers between the ages of 18 and 65 years that report non-zero wages and omits workers located at the bottom and top 0.5% of the wage distribution, some of the descriptive statistics presented in Table 1 seem counterintuitive and not in line with those commonly observed in the literature. This arises because other studies frequently do not distinguish between workers according to their income level, number of hours worked or status as salaried or self-employed workers.

13Among early studies, the original analysis by Brown et al. (1980) for the U.S. used eight categories; Miller (1987) used six occupations for the United Kingdom; Kidd (1993) used six categories for Australia; Kidd and Shannon (1994) used seven occupations for Canada; and Brown et al. (1999) used eight categories for Mexico.

14We originally intended to include the decomposition results at the three-digit level. Nonetheless, this greater disaggregation led to small cell sizes, i.e. less than 50 observations, in certain occupations particularly for women. As a result, we were forced to either group together occupations to increase their cell size or drop the occupations with small cell sizes from our sample. Neither of these alternatives is ideal since creating artificial groupings may generate misleading results, while the elimination of low-populated occupations would make our results non-comparable to those previously obtained.

15The first stage results which include the occupation specific wage regressions corrected for self-selection are available upon request.

16In results not presented, using additional information from a 10.0% random sample of the 1990 Census, the evolution of gender wage differentials from 1990 to 2010 was also examined. Changes in relative wages between male and female workers in Mexico since 1990 have been well documented, where special focus has been given to the impact of trade liberalisation on wages (e.g. Aguayo-Téllez et al., 2013) and the increase in female labour force participation rates (e.g. Duval and Orraca, 2011). It was observed that the gender wage gap steadily grew over time, standing at .013, .021 and .026 log points in 1990, 2000 and 2010, respectively. Regarding the BU component, it is estimated that the BU term decreased the gender wage gap by .090 and .103 log points in 1990 and 2000, respectively. By 2010, the role of occupational segregation in explaining gender wage differentials changed slightly, where it is estimated that the BU term decreased the gender wage gap by .085 log points.

Received: July 09, 2014; Accepted: February 16, 2015

Creative Commons License This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License